Building the Empire State. Brian Phillips Murphy

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Building the Empire State - Brian Phillips Murphy страница 9

Building the Empire State - Brian Phillips Murphy American Business, Politics, and Society

Скачать книгу

of this period.10 Histories of early American banking instead tend to settle their gaze on just one of these associations: the Bank of New-York. The reasons are understandable: it was the only one of the proposed banks to open its doors in 1784, it remained the city’s only bank until a branch of the Bank of the United States opened in 1791, and it operated under its own name until a 2007 merger. In addition, the bank has one particularly prominent name tied to its origin story: future Treasury secretary Alexander Hamilton. His role in the bank’s founding and early operations invites observers to view it as an intellectual antecedent of his political and economic philosophy in establishing the first Bank of the United States and a securitized, tradable national debt. Before one can understand Hamilton, the thinking goes, one must study “his” bank.11 Yet the Bank of New-York’s early years—the seven years it operated before it was incorporated—are often ignored in studies of early American finance that rely on quantitative data. The bank did not begin keeping a single set of archived account books or minutes of the meetings of its board of directors until the bank was chartered; therefore, the precise details of its finances remain opaque and unknowable. Approaching the Bank of New-York through Hamilton can be more distorting than illuminating. Hamilton’s position was initially tangential and his influence within the bank was diluted by other directors and shareholders. He owned, after all, just one symbolic share of its stock. Acting as an agent for two wealthy out-of-town merchants, Hamilton had initially planned to help them found their own bank. Once he learned that a coalition had already met to organize a commercially oriented bank, he joined that group and was welcomed by promoters who were as eager to gain access to two large investors as they were to Hamilton’s thoughts on finance. Therefore, studies of New York banks that fixate on Hamilton’s role at the Bank of New-York risk overstating his indispensability and overshadowing the institution’s more authentic originators: New York City merchants and the competition for charters in New York City during the winter and spring of 1784.

      The various bank cohorts in New York in 1784 were united by motivations to ameliorate ongoing tensions between New York’s Whigs and Tories by creating a venue for what Robert Livingston called “social intercourse” that would “wear down mutual prejudices.” The bank promoters agreed that anti-Tory politics were blinding both lawmakers and voters to the obvious contributions Tories could make to the city and nation’s commercial and political life, and there seemed to be no easy way to rhetorically persuade political leaders that their long-term self-interest lay in changing course. Moreover, none of the state’s existing institutions had the capacity to offer the favors, privileges, and opportunities that could reorganize the rivalries and contain the animosities threatening to destabilize the infant republic. As he watched the local economy of New York City deteriorate, Robert Livingston ridiculed the lack of money and credit in the city as “republican economics.” Having driven Tories and their capital abroad, the chancellor feared that New York would eventually have to go abroad in search of funds to operate its state government.

      Each pro-bank mobilization therefore sought to reach beyond rhetoric by launching an institution capable of offering financial incentives to Tories and Whigs who found common cause with one another, replacing mutual hostilities with transactional trust. Livingston thought a bank would aid New Yorkers in financing their own future and secure the confederation among the new states, “[helping] cement a union that separate [state] debts would weaken.”12 Alexander Hamilton and a group of Manhattan merchants shared similar views regarding the potential for commercial relationships to mend divisions between rival parties. Hamilton proposed that different interests not merely acknowledge mutual ambitions and symbiotic relationships but act on them, too. A bank could fulfill his wish to “make” durable alliances by encouraging Tories and Whigs to “participate” in the “privileges” of the new regime while resetting peacetime trade with Britain.13 The pro-bank activists of 1784 therefore considered commercial and business relationships to be essential features in the civic ecology of a stable and thriving state as well as a union of states. In this way, economic materialism did not merely peacefully coexist alongside democratic political institutions; instead, the two seemed to be fundamentally linked. Business interests tamed the passions and rivalries that deference, aristocracy, and politeness could not master. If the state created the market, the market in turn stabilized the state and gave it the capacity to govern.

      Beyond resuscitating the local economy and strengthening the nation’s prestige and power abroad, an incorporated bank would strengthen bank petitioners’ hands in New York State’s political arena. In replacing animosities with alliances, bankers would constrain the ability of New York politicians to continue to exploit anti-Tory sentiment among voters. On a practical level, Tory bank clients would quickly find themselves ensnared in legal contracts and credit relationships, making future legislative assaults more difficult to justify and frustrating to enforce. A Tory-Whig bank would place Tory capital beyond lawmakers’ reach by comingling Tories’ “Loyalist” assets and capital with those of “patriots,” thereby sheltering them from confiscation or seizure. Even as they were being asked for charters of incorporation, therefore, lawmakers were being kept in the dark about one of the true motives behind the pro-bank mobilizations of 1784: an incorporated bank, clothed in the legitimate authority of the state, would become an institutional counterweight to the state legislature. New York officials were being asked to create an institution that would be used to undermine their own governing agenda.

      The competing coalitions of 1784 shared another reason for wanting to found a bank in New York: neither the state nor city already had one. Although competition between banks was feared as a potentially destabilizing rivalry, the absence of institutional banking in New York meant that merchants and mechanics alike lacked a stable supply of money and credit, creating logistical challenges for individuals engaged in all kinds of transactions, from buying flour to paying taxes. As Alexander Hamilton argued in a 1783 letter to New York governor George Clinton, without an “incorporation of creditors in the nature of banks” people would be “deprive[d]” of “the benefit of an increased circulation” and would, “of course … [be] disable[d]” from “paying the taxes for want of a sufficient medium.” The consequences were both local and national: a lack of sound money and available credit constrained local commerce and injured the “national faith honor and reputation” of the United States as a whole. “It will be a shocking and indeed an eternal reproach of this country,” he wrote, “if we begin peaceable enjoyment of our independence by a violation of all the principles of honesty & true policy” because of an inability to conduct basic exchanges.14

      Yet despite their commonalities, the coalitions who petitioned the New York state legislature for a bank charter in 1784 had inherent differences. Each proposed to serve different interests by prioritizing different functions. The Bank of New-York opened as a money bank, meaning that its paper banknotes were backed by deposits of gold and silver coins called specie. Such a bank principally supported merchants engaged in importing goods to the city, investing in small manufacturing enterprises, and granting credit to each other and a limited circle of dependents. By contrast, the Livingston-backed Bank of the State of New York would be a land bank: its paper banknotes were to be backed with a portfolio of mortgaged lands as well as coins. Such a bank was designed to take advantage of a short-term depression in the city’s real estate market and provide a vehicle for converting existing land holdings into circulating money. Livingston hoped it would become a deposit institution for governments, churches, and charities, enabling the bank to pay regular dividends on its stock and become a profitable investment for its shareholders. Yet it would also inevitably and primarily benefit landowners.

      These distinctions are important. By proposing to tether paper banknotes to different forms of collateral, bank petitioners presented lawmakers with a choice about the future direction of the state’s economy. Determining which type of capital—land or coins—was more suitable as a basis for a financial institution’s operations would also determine what interests—landed or mercantile—would gain access to credit in the near future. This choice carried long-term implications for what kinds of economic activities would take root in New York and which professions—landlords or merchants, for example—would make decisions about how to allocate resources and

Скачать книгу