Disassembly Required. Geoff Mann

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Disassembly Required - Geoff Mann страница 3

Disassembly Required - Geoff Mann

Скачать книгу

capitalism, with particular attention to the origins and consolidation of global processes often called “neoliberalism” (Chapter 5), and then to “financialization” and the mechanisms behind the “subprime crisis” of 2007–2008 (Chapter 6). In this case, the devil is definitely in the details—but not exclusively. Chapter 7 is partly a reflection, in light of the political and economic crisis in Europe, on what the previous chapters can tell us about the material and ideological challenges facing alternatives to capitalism. It also considers the necessarily experimental and unclear ways we might demand not merely the end of capitalism, but the emergence of something better. Nothing in these conjectures is definitive or guaranteed. But the critic has a responsibility to say where his or her critique might lead. The wisdom and relevance of these propositions will only be visible in retrospect.

      Overall, the goal is to understand how and why capitalism works. Only then can we identify levers of change. “How” and “why” are two different questions. The first is a descriptive problem; the second is analytical, and at least partly historical. Ultimately, it is the analytical part that matters politically, because it requires an argument: these are the reasons why capitalism operates the way it does; it is these dynamics that inevitably fail to meet the needs of many; and these are the reasons there are better, fully realizable ways of organizing our lives. The emphasis throughout is on this analytical side; but we can only get there after getting the descriptive side down as well as possible. We need empirical material to work with, an understanding of the nuts and bolts of capitalist dynamics that is not exhaustive, but nonetheless fairly detailed and subtle.

      If Capitalism Is Something, What Kind of Thing Is It?

      The first thing we need to agree upon is that capitalism is something we can name, with distinctive features that distinguish it in non-trivial ways both from what came before and from other contemporary systems of economic organization. Capitalism is one way of arranging human society, of organizing the social relations of production, exchange, consumption, and distribution. We can call this arrangement, as Karl Marx did, a “mode of production,” but could just as easily call it a “mode of organizing economic activity,” or even simply an “economic system.”

      All three terms, one might say, get the point across. However, some precision is useful here. First, in today’s capitalist societies, “the economy” and things “economic” are depoliticized and oversimplified. For many, the “economic system” refers to specific dynamics associated with production and exchange in formal (i.e., legally recognized) markets. Rarely does it bring to mind things like women’s work in the home, the illicit drug trade, or the education system, even though these are significant components of modern capitalism. To understand modern political economic arrangements, we need language that reminds us explicitly of what they involve, and “the economy” or “economic system” do not do that work right now.

      The second reason we need specific terminology is the popular association of modern capitalism with “human nature.” It is fair to say that many people believe that the capitalist “economic system” is the logical outcome of “natural” human motivations and proclivities. Capitalism is taken not as an economic system, but as the economic system. Economic questions are taken to be synonymous with questions about capitalism. Indeed, capitalist political economy has become so dominant in our way of thinking that any economic relationship that is not capitalist is assumed to be somehow “distorted” or “fettered” by the state or some other institution. The assumption is that if an economy is not capitalist, it is either backward or underdeveloped (and thus not capitalist yet), or it is being purposely prevented from being capitalist, and would immediately “go capitalist” if left to its own. There is no historical evidence this is even close to true. Markets and states and human communities “go capitalist” when organized to do so.

      For these reasons, I think “mode of production” is preferable. It flags the fact that an economic system is always a way of organizing social relations. Capitalism, communism, socialism, and any other mode of production you can think of are all ways of organizing the production and reproduction of the system itself. They produce and maintain the ways we live. Thinking of capitalism as a mode of production thus allows us to include in the “economic” conversation the gendered division of labour in the household, which produces particular kinds of workers in capitalism. It allows us to recognize that the way we interact with and shape ecological systems is a key part of how we produce and reproduce our societies. It lets us look at the educational system as, in large part, a training in “economic participation.” The mode of production concept flags the fact that capitalism is not defined by factories and financial firms—there are both in non-capitalist societies—but by the societal norms and institutions in which they operate.

      What Makes Capitalism Capitalist?

      Capitalism emerged in Europe from so-called “precapitalist” modes of production (principally feudal and mercantilist) over a period of centuries. There are longstanding debates regarding precisely when, where, and why it emerged, how long it took, and who was involved, but there is a general consensus that by the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, what we now call capitalism was fairly well consolidated in England, and to a lesser extent in western Europe. Capitalism has since diffused, unevenly and incompletely, across the globe. Often it has done so through coercive means, including war and colonialism. In other places and times, it has spread in a less violent manner, either by simply providing people with what they wanted, or because it was embraced by those who believed it was the key to “development.” Consequently, capitalism does not look the same everywhere you go. Societies with other modes of production have inevitably adapted to capitalism, and adapted capitalism to fit. China, for example, has developed a very complicated relationship with capitalism over time, a relationship that continues to evolve.

Скачать книгу