Alternatives to Capitalism. Robin Hahnel

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Alternatives to Capitalism - Robin Hahnel страница 2

Автор:
Жанр:
Серия:
Издательство:
Alternatives to Capitalism - Robin Hahnel

Скачать книгу

in the 1990s, when the collapse of the USSR heralded a new era of capitalist triumphalism. Robin and his collaborator Michael Albert built on ideas that had emerged within the libertarian socialist tradition in the twentieth century—including council communists, anarcho-syndicalists and elements of the New Left—to develop a plausible anti-capitalist economic model known as “participatory economics.” This model dispenses with the defining features of a capitalist economy—private ownership, markets and a hierarchical division of labor—replacing them with self-managing worker and consumer councils, and a novel procedure of participatory planning. His latest book on the subject is Of the People, By the People: The Case for a Participatory Economy (AK Press, 2012), where he presents a comprehensive, yet accessible explanation of the model.

      In the 1990s Erik initiated the Real Utopias Project, editing a series of books canvassing and assessing a range of proposals for emancipatory institutional arrangements. This eventually led to the publication of his own work, Envisioning Real Utopias (Verso, 2010). By far the most ambitious book in the series, developed in part through a speaking tour of 18 countries over four years, it outlines a novel conception of socialism, anchored in the concept of “social empowerment”; a variety of general institutional configurations that could facilitate its realization; and a detailed discussion of strategy for social transformation.

      In Alternatives to Capitalism Erik and Robin bring to bear the ideas developed in Of the People, By the People and Envisioning Real Utopias. Part one focuses on participatory economics, while part two focuses on real utopian socialism. Each part opens with a lead essay that summarizes the main ideas of the author’s approach, followed by a critical commentary by the other author, followed by a rejoinder. The distinctive nature of this text is the depth of the dialogue that emerges. New arguments and ideas surface in each of the six contributions, while key issues are revisited throughout and subjected to sustained evaluation. The result is a work that, even as it covers a range of issues in economics, social theory and history, achieves a rare degree of depth and thoroughness.

      Important points of disagreement emerge. These concern, among other things, the level of detail to which post-capitalist visions should aspire, the future of markets, and whether a revolutionary strategy has a credible role to play in anti-capitalist politics. Readers will have to make their own judgments about the competing arguments on these issues—a task made easier by the constructive spirit with which Erik and Robin pursue their disagreements, with no time wasted on straw-manning or point scoring. This reflects the genuine political desire, shared by the authors and publishers, that motivates Alternatives to Capitalism: to strengthen the intellectual resources of anti-capitalist politics. We hope it makes a worthwhile contribution to this most vital of tasks.

PART ONE

       CHAPTER 1

       The Case for Participatory Economics

       Robin Hahnel

      Curious Jane: “So, if you don’t like capitalism, what do you want instead?”

      Modern anti-capitalist: “Certainly not old-style bureaucratic Communism!”

      Curious Jane: “Fine … But then what DO you want?”

      Modern anti-capitalist: “I want an economic system that promotes economic democracy, economic justice, and human solidarity, without sacrificing economic efficiency.”

      Curious Jane: “Who wouldn’t! … But people sometimes mean different things when they use these words. Can you be more specific?”

      Supporter of participatory economics: “Yes I can—and you are quite correct to demand clarification, because often disagreements over how best to organize the economic system stem from different conceptions of what these words mean. By economic democracy, I mean having decision making power in proportion to the degree one is affected by a decision. By economic justice, I mean economic reward commensurate with sacrifice, or effort. By human solidarity, I mean having concern for the wellbeing of others. And by economic efficiency, I mean using scarce productive resources where they are most socially beneficial and not wasting people’s hard work.”

      Curious Jane: “That is all well and good … I’m not sure I agree entirely with your definitions, but let’s suppose for now that I did. Exactly how would you organize the economy to achieve these goals?”

      The model of a participatory economy—which I briefly summarize below—is an answer to Jane’s last question. It is not an answer to other important questions, such as: In the short run, what can we do in the here and now to best promote the above goals? Or, in the long run, what strategy might maximize our chances of making a successful transition from the economics of competition and greed to an economics of equitable cooperation? These are important, but quite different questions. Participatory economics is simply a coherent description of how a fully developed system of equitable cooperation could function. It is not a transition strategy or political program.

       A Participatory Economy1

      The major institutions “we”2 propose to achieve economic democracy, economic justice, and human solidarity while protecting the environment and ensuring efficiency are: (1) self-governing democratic councils of workers and consumers where each member has one vote, (2) jobs balanced for empowerment and desirability by the members of worker councils themselves, (3) compensation according to effort as judged by one’s workmates, and (4) a participatory planning procedure in which councils and federations of workers and consumers propose and revise their own interrelated activities without central planners or markets, under rules designed to generate outcomes that are efficient, equitable, and environmentally sustainable.

      Over the past twenty years some critics have disagreed with our goals while others have objected to one or another of our recommendations for how to achieve them. Erik has offered his own evaluation of participatory economics on pages 252–65 of Envisioning Real Utopias.3 In my reading Erik seems to agree with our goals—although, as one would expect, his formulation and argument differ in some regards. Most importantly, and unlike many who have criticised participatory economics, Erik seems to share our views about what economic justice and economic democracy mean and require.

      Unless I am mistaken, Erik is also supportive of compensation based on effort and trying to balance jobs for desirability and empowerment, although he worries it may prove difficult to achieve these goals. To be specific, we propose that each worker council come up with its own procedures for assigning what we call “effort ratings” to one another, which become the basis for their members’ consumption rights in neighborhood consumption councils. We call this an effort-rating committee, but its composition and procedures are left up to each council, and we fully expect different worker councils to come up with very different ways to go about this. In particular, compensation is not something that can be negotiated when new members are hired by worker councils in a participatory economy. Everyone is free to apply for membership in any worker council of her choice, and worker councils are free to hire whomever they wish from their applicant pools—subject to strict rules outlawing discrimination of course. However, since remuneration is determined only after someone has worked, and is to be based only on differences in efforts, or sacrifices, as judged by co-workers, the hiring decision is completely separate

Скачать книгу