Oikos: God’s Big Word for a Small Planet. Andrew Francis

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Oikos: God’s Big Word for a Small Planet - Andrew Francis страница 5

Автор:
Серия:
Издательство:
Oikos: God’s Big Word for a Small Planet - Andrew  Francis

Скачать книгу

developed an administrative class separate from the clergy, but increasingly a social hierarchy that rewarded those loyal to the crown with land, wealth, title, and rule over the populace. Deep in English history, we know that the peasant class had subsistence lives without money, living in hovels, scratching a living from the land with occasional handouts from the lord of the manor in return for their agricultural labor and soldiering. People were kept in check by the supply of food. Just like my contemporaries with our bubble gum bank notes, folk learned to trade, with some becoming wealthy and selling either the products of their land or their skills in local markets. What began as a barter economy grew as cities minted their own currencies, while the lords of each manor accrued gold—in similar fashion to Venetians and their ducats. No wonder folklore developed their heroes, such as Robert the Bruce in Scotland or the mythical Robin Hood2 who “robbed the rich and gave to the poor” in England.

      It was traders from Italy (e.g., the Lombards) or itinerant Jewish moneylenders, such as Shakespeare’s Shylock in The Merchant of Venice, who began organizing promissory notes between differently located branches of their family. So someone could pay in gold in one country, traveling home in relative safety and redeeming their wealth later. By 1600, there was a well-established international economy. This was reflected in patterns of trade, the support of exploration and of such international “banking.”

      Learning from economic theory

      The jury remains out on Adam Smith. There are those who believe The Wealth of Nations is intentionally theological, with the social order built upon the concept of God acting within nature; others view him as skeptically deistic, because he never explicitly mentions God. Classical economists argue that Smith’s “wealth of nations” concept is supreme, promoting a “free market economy,” effectively dog-eat-dog, when only the most competitive will survive. Neoclassical economists emphasize Smith’s “invisible hand” concept, which presumes that when an individual acts in their best self-interest, it will benefit the whole society. However the faces of those spinning coins fall for you, Smith is still important because he mapped out the ground for economic discussion, while also stating:

      • The existence of obvious inequalities in bargaining power between workers and masters (capital holders);

      • That wages cannot be statutorily regulated because different market forces—such as supply and demand of labor—occur;

      • That all “subjects” should contribute towards the upkeep of the state, thus advocating progressive personal taxation and not just taxes upon goods and services.

      Western society was rapidly changing, from and around that First World War era. So-called laissez-faire economics, akin to Smith’s classical dog-eat-dog position, saying let the market decide who survives, was the favored model of the rich and/or politically powerful. During the 1920s boom, most Western governments agreed to link their currency rates (e.g., the US$–UK£ rate) to the price of gold, effectively tying their own currency to a particular value while also agreeing not to print more money than for which they had hard gold equivalence. This became known as “the gold standard,” creating a federalized money system without political union (akin to today’s Eurozone)—a voluntary straitjacket.

      • Was a worker paid a proper value for their labor, or were they just paid the minimum necessary for survival?

      • Was the value of a commodity recognized? E.g., food had huge human and market value whereas

Скачать книгу