Broken Cities. Deborah Potts

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Broken Cities - Deborah Potts страница 4

Broken Cities - Deborah Potts

Скачать книгу

to them because it would be exceedingly risky or very clearly would not be profitable. It is pointless to expect the large-scale private sector to lend money for housing to groups that it knows cannot pay that money back and/or whose tenure does not conform to the norms of capitalist private property. This is a circle that cannot be squared unless the iron rules of the market are set aside and the state intervenes with subsidies that make the processes profitable for the private-sector actors involved. This does work. However, it simultaneously proves the point: poor urban families cannot afford to be ‘formally’ housed under market conditions, and now that market conditions are globally hegemonic, this must be the starting point for all analyses of housing problems.

      

      An objection may be raised to the argument that the capitalist private sector cannot deliver ‘affordable’ housing for low-income groups on the grounds that this is not so obviously the case in the wealthier societies of the Global North, and that the lending practices of financial institutions in the USA and Europe during the early years of the twenty-first century disprove the point that such capitalist institutions will not lend to poorer groups for urban housing. To the contrary, however, the absolute disaster that followed in 2007–08 with the global financial crash proves the point entirely. First, the iron rules of the market did eventually assert themselves and demonstrated in the most destructive fashion that lower-income groups even in the Global North could not afford private-sector housing. And second, the housing circle was, as usual, squared by massive intervention, at almost unimaginable levels, into the markets by the state sector in these societies. Trillions of tax dollars were poured into the financial institutions involved in housing loans. They were saved and a massive global depression was avoided, but the world has still not recovered from the colossal debts imposed on states and the austerity programmes that followed.

      

      2. The impact of the neoliberal phase

      In the 1980s a new phase of capitalism based on neoliberal ideology began to replace the more regulated and state-interventionist types of capitalism that had been typical in post-war Global North societies. The second premise is that this neoliberal turn exacerbated the urban housing issues that will always exist in a capitalist society. It should be noted here that a distinction is being drawn between the impacts on urban housing of the essential requirements of any variety of capitalism, as discussed above, and the conditions encouraged by neoliberal capitalist ideology. This is analytically helpful, as, quite rightly, urban scholars critique the idea that neoliberalism is at the root of all inequalities and urban problems, especially given that many of these pre-date the 1980s. In essence, the neoliberal turn promoted a much stronger reliance on market forces for determining how resources were allocated and a much reduced role for government. Public expenditure came to be seen as something to be cut wherever possible. Given the situation outlined above whereby it is largely inevitable that affordable formal-sector housing for poorer people is achievable only through state intervention in the market, the problems that neoliberal ideology create for urban housing are obvious. In both the rich and poor parts of the world the same processes emerged. Governments and development agencies of all types sought to find ways to impose full cost recovery on housing programmes for the poor at the very least, and preferably to shift the burden of provision to the large-scale private sector, which, it was argued, was more efficient and skilled due to the disciplines imposed by the requirement to make a profit. Unfortunately, that is the very requirement that simultaneously makes affordable low-income housing impossible for the private sector to provide. Functioning and long-standing public-sector large-scale provision of affordable urban housing – such as council housing in the UK – was also deemed to be inherently wrong under the new ideology because it was not market-oriented and was such a significant element of government budgets. As a 2017 EU report, The State of Housing in the EU, states: ‘In most cases policy responses at Member States level have been to decrease public expenditure for housing and … [to rely] on measures to increase the supply in the private sector or access to homeownership.’1 The gradual undermining and reduction of the public sector across the Global North has served to make the crisis of the shortage of affordable housing in cities very much worse. Recognition of the ideological underpinnings of this situation is crucial – the conditions are not inherent in the way that the profit motive is for capitalism as a mode of production – these are political choices about what is claimed to be ‘right’. Since subsidies are seen as inherently wrong, and somehow even dangerous, this has created a fundamental constraint on the types of affordable housing solutions deemed acceptable and limits the policy conversations that are possible.

      

      3. Segmented housing demand

      The simple logic of the rule that prices are set by supply and demand is the default mindset of most housing policymakers and housing analysts. But the understanding tends to be simplistic. The general argument made is that the more urban housing is built, the lower the prices will become, and that this means that eventually they will become low enough to be affordable for the poorer groups. This mindset relates to the formal, planned housing sector – the messy unplanned markets of informal settlements in the Global South are deemed to be ‘problems’ that might be alleviated by the achievement of affordable housing in the formal market system. For the sake of argument, it helps to set informal housing aside at this point. The focus for the moment is on the planned and legally constituted housing markets.

      It is also understood by most analysts that because houses actually have to be located in particular places, unlike most other goods, then the provision of urban land for housing is an essential element of the supply and demand equation. Indeed, inadequate provision of planned land – lack of land supply – is often pinpointed as the reason why housing is unaffordable for so many urban families, shifting the focus to land rather than buildings. For pro-market protagonists, this also has the benefit of shifting the ‘blame’ onto governments, since these nearly always play key roles in determining which urban land can legally be used for new housing, and away from the constraints imposed by relying on private profit-oriented suppliers.

      

      The land issue is important but it is not the panacea so often assumed. The problem is that it is quite possible – indeed it is common – to have land occupied by empty housing units, including new-build houses, across a city at the same time that many poorer groups cannot afford to buy or rent legal, planned housing. The issue that is insufficiently recognised in the simple supply/demand analyses, or possibly dismissed because it is an ‘inconvenient truth’, is that housing markets are segmented. Increasing the supply of most types of housing makes no difference to the housing problems faced by the poorer groups as they cannot afford ‘most types of housing’. This is true in poor and rich countries – the same processes play out whether you are in Harare, Zimbabwe or Haringey in London, places with which I am deeply familiar (as noted in the Foreword). Housing that is affordable for such groups is a different sort of housing with a separate set of market conditions. This makes the measurement and conceptualisation of what is ‘affordable housing’ deeply political.

      The significance of segmented markets is well developed in studies of labour and migration to cities, especially international migration to global cities.2 It is obvious that there are different types of labour (skilled, semi-skilled, unskilled) and that, in any one city, demand for each type will vary. If internal labour migration cannot meet demands, then international migrants may fill the gaps. But the gaps are specific – the classic division being between demands for very low-paid service-sector workers (such as cleaners) because insufficient numbers of local workers will (or can afford to) work at these pay levels, and separate demands for highly paid skilled professionals (in IT or the finance sectors, for example) where a lack of domestic supply is ‘real’. As research on the associated migration streams demonstrates, these different groups are treated very differently in terms of immigration laws, etc. And just as there are segmented markets in labour, there are segmented markets in housing. In the same way that a plentiful supply of skilled financiers will not meet any unmet demand

Скачать книгу