Levers of Power. Kevin A. Young

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Levers of Power - Kevin A. Young страница 7

Levers of Power - Kevin A. Young

Скачать книгу

business and state elites, but popular forces also possess tremendous power of disruption.45 That power often lies dormant, but the potential is always there. The presence, intensity, and duration of popular disruption is often the most decisive factor in shaping policy. When mass resistance is disruptive and sustained, it greatly expands the potential for progressive reform, often forcing new policy options onto the table. It can compel politicians to pursue legislation they dislike, and can shape how that legislation is implemented. When mass resistance is absent or merely episodic, business and state elites will call the shots. Non-elites may get a few crumbs as a byproduct of intra-elite conflicts or elections, but any progressive reform will be much weaker and more subject to reversal. A major reason why Obamaera progressive reforms were so tepid is that the Obama years lacked the sustained mass disruption present in other eras of US history. There were some notable examples of mobilization like Occupy Wall Street and black resistance to police violence, but they were not nearly as disruptive as the movements of the 1930s and the 1960s. In the chapters that follow, we draw from both the Obama era and from twentieth-century examples to indicate when and how progressive movements have had the greatest impact on government policy.46

      A Counter-Intuitive Strategy for Social Movements

      Our central argument in this regard is that mass resistance is most effective when it directly targets corporations and state agencies. By threatening the profits or the functioning of those institutions, popular disruption can compel their leaders to accept progressive changes in government policy. Since these elites are usually the key roadblocks to change, and since they possess enormous power over what the government does, it makes more sense to target them than to focus on elected politicians. Their responsiveness to movement demands doesn’t spring from their goodwill, but from a rational cost-benefit analysis of their interests. If subjected to mass pressures that disrupt their profit-making or their institutional functioning, these leaders will naturally seek to cut their losses. Conceding to movement demands often becomes the lesser-evil option. If movements can force a change in these elites’ cost-benefit calculations, progressive government action then becomes much more likely.

      Nonetheless, some of the most successful progressive movements in US history have focused their energies mainly on non-electoral targets. Auto companies in the 1930s grudgingly accepted the unionization of their workers because they faced unprecedented strikes and disruptions on the shop floor. Most labor organizers spent far less time trying to get Democrats elected than on organizing their fellow workers to bring their workplaces to a halt. Franklin Roosevelt was elected in 1932 and reelected in 1936, but workers only succeeded in winning effective unionization rights when they completely disrupted industry and forced the bosses to concede those rights. We examine this process in Chapters 1 and 4.

Скачать книгу