Environment and Society. Paul Robbins

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Environment and Society - Paul Robbins страница 29

Environment and Society - Paul Robbins

Скачать книгу

product, which might include short text, photos, slogans, catchphrases, or even a jingle. This will necessarily include some information to prove that your innovation is actually an environmental improvement over the status quo. What would actually make such an alternative compelling, especially if it is more expensive?

      Exercise 3.3 Thinking Economically

      References

      1 Beder, S. (1996). Charging the earth: the promotion of price-based measures for pollution control. Ecological Economics 16 (1): 51–63.

      2 Coase, R.H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3 (October): 1–44.

      3 Ehrlich, P.R. (1968). The Population Bomb. New York: Ballantine Books.

      4 Field, B.C. (2005). Natural Resource Economics: An Introduction. Long Grove, IL: Waveland Press.

      5 Harvey, D. (1996). Justice, Nature, and the Geography of Difference. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.

      6 Rees, J. (1990). Natural Resources: Allocation, Economics, and Policy. New York: Routledge.

      7 Robertson, M.M. (2006). The nature that capital can see: science, state, and market in the commodification of ecosystem services. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space 24 (3): 367–387.

      8 Sabin, P. (2013). The Bet: Paul Ehrlich, Julian Simon, and Our Gamble over Earth’s Future. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

      9 Simon, J.L. (1980). Resources, population, environment: an oversupply of false bad news. Science 208 (4451): 1431–1437.

      10 TerraChoice Environmental Marketing Inc. (2007). The Six Sins of Greenwashing: A Study of Environmental Claims in North American Consumer Markets. Reading, PA: Author.

      11 Tierney, J. (1990). Betting on the planet. The New York Times, December 2, pp. 52–53, 76–81.

      Suggested Reading

      1 Crook, C. and Clapp, R.A. (1998). Is market-oriented forest conservation a contradiction in terms? Environmental Conservation 25 (2): 131–145.

      2 Field, B.C. (2001). Natural Resource Economics: An Introduction. Long Grove, IL: Waveland Press.

      3 Godal, O., Ermoliev, Y., Klaassen, G. et al. (2003). Carbon trading with imperfectly observable emissions. Environmental and Resource Economics 25 (2): 151–169.

      4 Johnson, E. and Heinen, R. (2004). Carbon trading: time for industry involvement. Environment International 30 (2): 279–288.

      5 Randall, A. (1983). The problem of market failure. Natural Resources Journal 23: 131–148.

      6 Rees, J. (1990). Natural Resources: Allocation, Economics, and Policy. New York: Routledge.

      7 Robertson, M.M. (2006). Emerging ecosystem service markets: trends in a decade of entrepreneurial wetland banking. Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment 4 (6): 297–302.

      8 Sen, A.K. (2001). Development as Freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

      9 Taylor, P.L., Murray, D.L., and Reynolds, L.T. (2005). Keeping trade fair: governance challenges in the fair trade coffee initiative. Sustainable Development 13 (3): 199–208.

      Keywords

       Common property

       Game theory Institutions

       Prisoner’s Dilemma.

      Source: iko/Shutterstock.

      Chapter Menu

      Controlling Carbon?

      The Prisoner’s Dilemma

      The Tragedy of the Commons

      The Evidence and Logic of Collective Action

      Crafting Sustainable Environmental Institutions

      Are All Commoners Equal? Does Scale Matter?

      Thinking with Institutions

      There is a growing consensus on the science of climate change and the urgency of the problem. According to the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, whose job it is to vet the science surrounding global warming, global temperatures are rising, sea-level rise is expected, water availability may be impeded, and extreme weather events are likely to become more common and more severe. These changes will be felt unevenly but no country will be immune to such effects.

      Given the widespread and severe nature of the problem, why are global carbon emissions so hard to control? One might think of many good reasons for this to be true. People tend to ignore problems they cannot see, governments are under the influence of oil companies, and so on.

      One compelling argument holds that the root of the problem is that carbon quite simply does not stay put. With every combustion event (driving a car, burning a log, firing a coal plant for electricity, etc.) the carbon that is released quickly finds its way into the atmosphere. Carbon released in one country is – instantly – a burden shared by all countries. From the point of view of any individual country, moreover, carbon reductions are not “free,” since they require creating new rules, potentially reducing or redirecting economic production. A “carbon-reduced” product – whether a car, computer, or vegetable – may be more difficult to produce than its “status quo” counterpart. If such a product is more expensive as a result, it may not be competitive on a global market, especially if it must compete against products produced where carbon reductions have not been imposed. Many governments, including that of the United States, therefore express fear that if they make sacrifices in this direction while others do not, they will no longer be competitive. The benefits of carbon reduction, in a parallel way, would be experienced by all countries, but must be paid for by individual countries.

      For many environmental problems, costs are often borne collectively, while benefits accrue to individuals; on the other hand, individual costs may lead to collective benefits. Nations must cooperate where there is no “super-government” to impose environmental laws and where there

Скачать книгу