Competitive Advantage in Investing. Steven Abrahams
Чтение книги онлайн.
Читать онлайн книгу Competitive Advantage in Investing - Steven Abrahams страница 11
The simple idea of the reliability or variance of returns makes it easier to compare investment returns, including returns on investments that might otherwise seem wildly different. Almost every investment leaves a trail of returns with an average rate of return and variability around that average. An investor can measure variability by a wide set of measures: variance or standard deviation, the ratio of winning days to losing, the largest loss, and so on. They all get at a different facet of risk. A stock or a portfolio of stocks, a bond or a portfolio of bonds, options, real estate, commodities, mutual and hedge funds, and so on all leave a record. All investments leave a trail of returns as distinct as a fingerprint.
Markowitz's emphasis on risk and return encourages investors to compare investments on these two attributes. An investor could take more risk to get more return. But an investor also could compare investments with roughly the same risk and choose the one with the highest return. An investor alternatively could compare investments with similar returns and choose the one with the lowest risk. And an investor could take a view on the future risk and future return of a menu of investments. Investing suddenly becomes an exercise in trading off risk against return.
Investors trading off risk against return should transform the relative value of different assets. For assets with roughly the same risk, the one with the highest return would attract more investment. Its price would rise relative to others and its return would fall. Returns across assets in that sleeve of risk would tend to converge. For assets with roughly the same return, the one with the lowest risk would attract investment. Relative prices and returns would start to shift.
If an investor could go through all possible combinations of potential investments—all the items on our infinite list—the analysis leads to a set of portfolios that have both the highest return for a given level of risk and the lowest risk for a given level of return. These portfolios are the most efficient. Among all possible portfolios of investible assets, the efficient ones line up along a continuum or border from a point with the lowest risk and lowest return to a point with the highest risk and highest return. This becomes the efficient investment frontier (figure 1.1).
It is easy to miss the genius in Markowitz's formulation of risk and return. By bringing risk into the picture, Markowitz puts the least tangible element of investing on par with the most. Return is tangible, easy to measure and compare. It gets reported every day, every month, every year. Return can actually buy things. Risk, however, only shapes returns over time, has to be imagined in advance, and often is clear only in hindsight. Risk rarely shows up in summaries of investment performance. We tell ourselves stories of likely investment return, and, in an effort to convince ourselves or convince others, we tend to narrow the range of likely risk. Markowitz makes risk and return equals.
Figure 1.1 Markowitz's approach leads to a limited combination of securities that have the highest return for a given a level of risk or the lowest risk for a given level of return.
The Surprising Power of Diversification
Markowitz would have taken an important step if he had only made risk and return equals, but he has another idea that revolutionizes investing: investors can improve risk and return in a portfolio by mixing investments. In other words, investors have something valuable to gain from diversification.
To get an intuition for diversification, think again about a company that flips a coin every year and pays $2 for heads and $0 for tails. Then imagine a second company that flips a second coin and also pays $2 for heads and $0 for tails. Each company would pay $1 a year on average with a variance of $1.4 But because the two companies flip separate coins, they don't always pay on the same schedule. Some years, both will pay and investors will get $4. Other years, both will skip payments and investors will get $0. Most years, one or the other will pay, and investors will get $2. The companies still pay their separate cash flows, but the combination over time is smoother. In other words, the combination of the two companies doesn't reduce their expected return, but it does reduce their risk.
To Markowitz, mixed investment or diversification recognizes the unmeasured aspects of an investment that might make its returns move a little differently or very differently from all the investments around it. Diversification brought humility to investing. By diversifying, the investor would have to acknowledge that he or she would never know the likely timing, direction, or magnitude of returns of all the items on our infinite investment list. Diversification encourages adding a wide range of investments to a portfolio to capture the widest range of possible risks and returns.
Diversification might have sounded like just another nice idea if Markowitz had not provided a powerful example of its benefits. Markowitz measured diversification by the correlation between investment returns, or how much returns on different investments move together. Investments with returns that move proportionately up and down by the same amount at the same time would have a correlation of 1 (figure 1.2). Returns that moved proportionately in opposite directions at different times would have a correlation of −1. Investments with returns that have no relationship would have a correlation of 0, such as the two companies that flipped coins. Two investments with the same risk and same return but with a correlation of less than 1, for example, could combine into an investment with the same return but less risk.5 An investor who put the two coin-flipping companies into a portfolio would end up with an investment that returned $1 a year on average but had less than two-thirds of the risk of holding either company alone. The cash flow from the portfolio would be smoother than from either company alone. This is Markowitz's powerful insight on the benefit of diversification.
Figure 1.2 The periodic returns on different assets can vary together, with the correlation ranging from perfectly positive (1) to perfectly negative (−1) to anywhere in between.
Figure 1.3 Markowitz also showed that risk in a portfolio falls as the correlation between investments drops below 1.
Markowitz's insight leads to a finer appreciation for the ways investors could shape the risk and return of a portfolio by mixing different assets. The expected return from mixing assets would simply add up to the expected return from each investment, weighted, of course, by the share of the portfolio invested in each one. But the expected risk depended on the correlation between assets. Assets with a high positive correlation would simply be a weighted sum of the risk in each investment. But as the correlation fell, risk would fall, too (figure 1.3). And if an investor could add items that tended to spin off positive returns when others were spinning off negative—items with negative correlation—then risk could fall dramatically.
By showing that investors