Commodification and Its Discontents. Nicholas Abercrombie

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Commodification and Its Discontents - Nicholas Abercrombie страница 10

Commodification and Its Discontents - Nicholas  Abercrombie

Скачать книгу

cede rights of control to others by leasing or licensing. In leasing, a tenant is granted exclusive possession for a fixed term in exchange for a payment. But there are a bewildering number of varieties of this arrangement. Similarly, licenses can vary from a simple permission to be on someone’s land to a more proprietorial interest. Or the extent of a landowner’s control may be circumscribed by restrictive covenants or by devices such as easements, rent charges, mortgage charges or rights of entry. However, in modern times, by far the most significant cause of restriction on property rights arises out of the activities of the state, especially in planning legislation and environmental protection. Gray and Gray (2007: 420) argue that the contemporary view of property law is in stark contrast with the absolutist view of earlier times:

      And they conclude:

      The role of government in the regulation of land use … is now so pervasive that ‘property’ in land is often said to have taken on the character of a kind of social stewardship … ‘Property’ can therefore be conceptualised as involving – on a vast scale – the distribution by the state of user rights which are heavily conditioned and delimited by the public interest … On this view, ‘property’ in land comprises not so much a ‘bundle of rights’, but rather a form of delegated responsibility for land as a valuable community resource. (Gray and Gray, 2007: 55)

      Restrictions, by the state, on property rights in the name of the collective interest are an intervention in the market for land and constitute resistance to commodification. How, then, did this increased role for the state come about?

      Many of the elements of public policy and subsequent legislation introduced by the state, including restrictions on working hours, reform of the Poor Law, the slow enhancement of the powers and efficiency of local government, and improvements in sanitation, had implications for the management of land. In particular, local authorities became responsible for implementing legislation introduced by central government, and that was a major stimulus in making them more efficient and democratic. In the second half of the nineteenth century, measures for the improvement of drainage, provision of an adequate water supply, removal of refuse, control of street widths, structural safety and building heights, requirement for the submission of building plans before work began, use of powers to demolish, and then replace, insanitary houses following compulsory purchase, and the provision of open spaces and adequate roads all passed through local authorities. There was a steady flow of public health and housing legislation (Ashworth, 1954; Broadbent, 1977). Progress was slow, and resisted, but towards the end of the nineteenth century the basis for systematic town planning in the collective interest and as a function of an interventionist state at national and local levels had been constructed.

      Between the closing years of the nineteenth century and the beginning of the First World War, town planning as a movement gradually took shape (Tichelar, 2018b). The term ‘town planning’ was first employed in Britain in the 1909 Act and it was used not only for a set of statutory powers, but also to describe a professional activity with appropriate training. A professional body – the Town Planning Institute – was set up in 1914 and now describes itself as the largest town planning institute in Europe and the ‘UK’s leading planning body for spatial, sustainable and inclusive planning’ (Royal Town Planning Institute, n.d.). Schemes for the construction of entire towns abounded, the best known of which was Ebenezer Howard’s plan for garden cities, originally published in 1902 (Howard, 1965). Importantly, Howard’s proposal combined an aesthetic interest with the provision of healthful housing, and that same combination informed the building of two actual garden cities: Letchworth (begun in 1904) and Welwyn (begun in 1919). Despite the fact that only two were built, the Garden Cities movement remained influential in British town planning in the development after the Second World War of New Towns, mostly seen as a solution to London’s housing problem, and, probably more significantly, in the way in which suburban locations were favoured for new housing throughout the twentieth century.

      The

Скачать книгу