Wealth. Yuval Elmelech

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Wealth - Yuval Elmelech страница 17

Wealth - Yuval Elmelech

Скачать книгу

2017). Consequently, as the structure and function of the family become more diverse in industrialized societies with rising rates of cohabitation, childlessness, divorce, and single-living, both individual and family attributes should be considered in wealth analysis.

      The LCH has also inspired prolific research into, and extensive debates about, the actual contribution of savings made out of income to wealth accumulation processes; and, particularly, it has stimulated debates about the muted role of intergenerational transfers in the model. Estimates of the share of household total net worth that can be traced back to intergenerational transfers—passed down from older to younger generations—range from less than a quarter to more than three quarters. Gale and Scholz’s (1994) estimates of the US data concluded that most of the accumulated wealth could be attributed to intergenerational transfers rather than to life-cycle savings. An analysis of more recent data from the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) (1989–2007) suggests that almost 40% of the wealth accumulated by older American households has its origins in intergenerational transfers (Wolff and Gittleman 2014). Wolff (2017: 261), however, notes that, when the sample is restricted to the bottom 95% of the population, the explanatory power of the life-cycle model, with its emphasis on savings out of income, is substantial.

      A “chain” of markets and domains

      Another deviation from the more established research on social mobility, with its focus on labor market attainment, is the multiplicity of domains and markets within which wealth accumulates through the exchange of goods and services. Savings made out of labor income capture only one, albeit important, segment in the chain that constitutes wealth mobility over the life course. In addition to earnings, households’ efforts to secure loans in order to purchase a car or start a business, to gain access to retirement plans and have control over investment decisions, and to find safe and affordable housing are but a few examples of household financial activities and of the numerous market transactions that influence asset ownership, portfolios, and total net worth.

      A revised life-course model of wealth accumulation—one that addresses the changing patterns of family transfers and the role of markets in economically advanced societies—provides a helpful explanation for wealth mobility in aging societies but does not explicitly address the question of inequality. However, wealth’s cumulative nature means that it is not difficult to envision how systematic disparities in access to family transfers (endowments) or to favorable market transactions would result in growing inequality.

      The tortoise and the hare: A wealth tale

      Aesop’s fable “The Tortoise and the Hare” is a tale about a contest between unequal partners. A hare brags about his speed and challenges a tortoise to a race. Noticing that he is well ahead of the tortoise halfway through the race, the confident hare decides to take a nap at the side of the road. When he wakes up, the hare continues the race and arrives at the finish line; but the tortoise, who has continued to plod along all the while, is already waiting for him there. The tortoise is declared the winner (visit http://read.gov/aesop/025.html for a digital version).

      The wealth version of the tale has a different ending. Not only does the hare start the race from an advanced position, ahead of the tortoise, but it is impossible for the tortoise to arrive at the finish line on its own. Furthermore, even when the wealthy hare stops to take a nap—or, as sociologist C. Wright Mills (1956: 111) said of the conditions governing wealth mobility among members of the elite, “even for a man in a coma”—he will continue to be ahead of the asset-poor tortoise on the wealth ladder.

      Studying what he terms the “power elite,” Mills (1956) describes a two-stage process of wealth accumulation in the hands of the elite: the “Big Jump” and the “Accumulation of Advantage.” The Big Jump, defined as “an opportunity to command a large sum of financial resources,” describes the starting point of the process. Since only a small percentage of households experience such a jump, inequality in economic resources by family of origin is where scholars of wealth stratification look for information on the formation of initial advantages. In addition to inequality at the point of initiation (endowments or lack thereof), the direction and gradient of mobility over the family life course are neither uniform nor universal. As noted earlier, the process of wealth accumulation involves distinct opportunities that people experience over the life course both in the private, familial sphere—intragenerational exchanges, such as assortative mating, income pooling, and economies of scale (Sweeney and Cancian 2004; Charles et al. 2013), and intergenerational wealth transfers that pass down from older to younger generations (Albertini et al. 2007)—and in the public sphere, in the form of rewards in various domains and markets, from education to earnings to profitable financial investments.

      Importantly, as the following chapters will reveal, life-course trajectories in the domestic or family sphere and in the public sphere of domains and markets are strongly interdependent, and within each sphere trajectories are often path-dependent and have enduring consequences for wealth attainment. Scholars of stratification note that advantages early in life can lead to exponential growth in socioeconomic returns later in life; early disadvantages, on the other hand, often lead to additional handicaps and downward social mobility. The systematic pattern of these processes—a pattern captured by the “cumulative advantage/disadvantage” (CA/D) framework (Merton 1968, 1995; DiPrete and Eirich 2006)—results in rising inequality.

      Observing substantial inequality in the publication records of renowned scientists and their less credited colleagues, sociologist Robert Merton coined the term “the Matthew effect” to describe a systematic and self-amplifying process of cumulative advantage (CA):

      By

Скачать книгу