Shattered Consensus. James Piereson

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Shattered Consensus - James Piereson страница 6

Shattered Consensus - James Piereson

Скачать книгу

iteration of this process has played out in higher education, where the liberal-left has seized nearly total control, to the point that conservatives are hard to find on major college faculties. As I argue in “The Left University,” the American university evolved roughly in tandem with American liberalism. In the early decades of the twentieth century, Progressives invented a public or political purpose for higher education when they argued that professors and university-trained researchers could staff government bureaus and regulatory bodies as neutral experts to act in the public interest. The university, it was argued, would stand above and outside politics, in contrast to economic groups like corporations and labor unions. Liberals in this way gradually took control of higher education under the conceit that their research agenda was neutral or objective in matters of politics and policy. Later, in response to the activism of the 1960s, university faculties embraced the new doctrines of feminism, environmentalism, group rights, diversity, and cultural change, at exactly the same moment as liberals outside the academy began to embrace them. It was not long thereafter when liberals came to dominate the Democratic Party. By the late 1970s, the politics of the American university looked very much like those of the national Democratic Party.

      Naturally, conservatives and Republicans are about as welcome in that academic setting as they would be at a Democratic national convention. In response, they set up their own intellectual institutions to provide an outlet for their views and to counter the influence of the academy. Here, as in other areas of national life, the opposing sides in the national debate have retreated into their respective subcultures.

      * * *

      Shattered Consensus outlines the lineaments of the postwar consensus and the gradual process by which it has come apart. It does not endeavor to specify when or how the current regime will fall or what will replace it. Rather, it only suggests that a certain degree of consensus is required in order for a polity to meet its major challenges and argues that such a consensus no longer exists in the United States. That being so, the problems will mount to a point of crisis where either they will be addressed through a “fourth revolution” or the polity will begin to disintegrate for lack of fundamental agreement.

      This forecast of a “fourth revolution” in the years ahead does not mean that Americans should be hoarding gold or stockpiling canned food. The end of the postwar regime need not bring about the end of America. On the contrary, it could open a dynamic new chapter in the American story. The journey is likely to be difficult, but Americans are obliged to remain optimistic even as they contemplate impending upheavals. The United States has survived such upheavals in the past, and a case could be made that the nation has grown and prospered as a result. It could do so again.

       PART ONE

       The Political Economy of the Postwar Order

       CHAPTER ONE

       John Maynard Keynes and the Collapse of the Old Order

      John Maynard Keynes was a liberal revolutionary who aimed to place the capitalist order on new economic, political, and cultural foundations. Not solely an economic theorist, he was a political economist in the tradition of Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, Schumpeter, and Hayek. His theories pointed toward a far-reaching revision in the relationship between the state and the economy in capitalist systems. While the institutions of government inherited from the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries had been designed to check the power of the state for the purpose of protecting liberty, Keynes assigned new power to the state in order to promote stable economic growth and full employment.

      The Keynesian revolution in economics thus implied a second revolution in politics, to circumvent both the constitutional and the cultural barriers to state action that had been erected in the era of classical liberalism. The “Keynesian state” is larger and far more interventionist than the forms of government anticipated by Adam Smith, the authors of the U.S. Constitution, and nearly all of the influential statesmen and theorists of the nineteenth century. Many of the core conflicts of our time grow out of the friction between Keynes’s vision of a managed economy and the constitutional order crafted to achieve quite different and far more limited goals.

      Keynes was sensitive to the historical nature of the capitalist system as it evolved through different phases, created new institutional forms, and adapted to crises and new challenges. He questioned whether it was still appropriate to use theories formulated in 1800 or 1850 to account for the economic realities of the 1920s and 1930s. The “age of laissez-faire,” he wrote in the 1920s, had been brought to an end first by the development of large corporations and labor unions, and then by the destructive effects of the world war. If the old order was dead, then a new one must be built on a different intellectual basis. This was the campaign that Keynes engaged in during his stints in public service and in the books and articles that he wrote between 1919 and his death in 1946.

      * * *

      A thinker of the widest interests, Keynes wrote on subjects ranging from Isaac Newton to modern art, and interspersed his treatises on economics with sage references to history, politics, and psychology. His biographer Robert Skidelsky asserts that he was as much a moralist as an economist.1 Keynes, he wrote, searched for a vision of capitalism that promoted both efficiency and justice in equal parts. In an essay on Alfred Marshall, his mentor at the University of Cambridge, Keynes wrote that the “master economist” must possess many gifts: “He must be a mathematician, historian, statesman, and philosopher, in some degree. No part of man’s nature or his institutions can be outside his regard.”2 Nor was Keynes an “armchair” or merely academic theorist; he participated actively in every important political debate that took place in Great Britain during the tumultuous years from the outbreak of World War I through the close of World War II. Progress in economics, he maintained, must arise from the interplay between theory and urgent practical problems.

      Keynes thus began working out his theories on the necessity of refashioning the capitalist order while he served as a member of the British delegation to the Paris Peace Conference in 1919. For Keynes and his generation, the Great War of 1914–1918 demolished the foundations of European civilization. The old order in Europe had been built upon a network of interlocking principles and ideals: Protestantism and Victorian morals in culture; nationalism, empire, and monarchy in politics; laissez-faire, free trade, and the gold standard in economics. The big question after the war was whether those principles and institutions could survive in a new era of sovereign debt, despair and dashed hopes, debauched currencies, and a permanently changed balance of world power.

      Keynes set forth his reflections on the war and the damage it did to the social order in The Economic Consequences of the Peace, the no-holds-barred attack on the Treaty of Versailles that he wrote in a few months in 1919 after the peace conference had concluded.3 He predicted that unless the treaty was revised, it would lead to financial ruin across Europe and possibly to another, more destructive war. The book was an immediate bestseller, turning Keynes into an international celebrity. It ran through five editions and was translated into eleven languages within a few years. Today it is regarded as one of the more important and controversial books published in the twentieth century, for in it Keynes not only criticized the treaty but declared the obsolescence of the prewar order in Europe along with its associated institutions, ideals, and cultural assumptions.

      He began the book with an insightful chapter titled “Europe before the War,” a melancholic reflection on a golden age blasted away on the battlefields of France and Belgium. “What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man that age was that came to an end in August, 1914,” he wrote.4 Keynes marveled at the progress made

Скачать книгу