Applied Mergers and Acquisitions. Robert F. Bruner

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Applied Mergers and Acquisitions - Robert F. Bruner страница 34

Applied Mergers and Acquisitions - Robert F. Bruner

Скачать книгу

      Some of the most interesting reflections on ethics in business emerge in dilemmas between two “bads” (i.e., asking which is less bad) or two “goods” (i.e., asking which is better). Choosing one ultimately impinges on another good, or perhaps commits a bad in the process. Consider the case of the attempted takeover of Walt Disney Productions by the corporate raider Saul Steinberg in June 1984. Disney’s CEO, Ronald Miller, faced the dilemma of whether to fight the takeover or pay “greenmail” to make Steinberg go away. The case discussion here highlights the kind of ethical considerations that Laura Nash’s framework can address.

      Assessment of the Problem

      Origins of the Problem

      In large part, Disney brought the unsolicited tender offer upon itself. Since the death of the founder, Walt Disney, in 1966, the firm had invested heavily in projects that failed to provide an adequate return. This led to a depressed share price. But the firm also retained assets such as a film library and valuable raw land in Florida that might be sold at a high profit. Steinberg saw this opportunity to buy Disney, restructure the firm, and earn a sizable return.

      One significant influence in this problem was the intrinsic value of Disney. Before the hostile bid, Disney’s shares were trading around $47.50 apiece. Steinberg revealed in a filing with the SEC that he paid an average of $63.25 per share to acquire a toehold stake in Disney before mounting his hostile bid. This suggested that he estimated the true value of Disney to be something greater than his cost basis. The estimates of securities analysts at C. J. Lawrence ($64.00 to $99.00/share) and Goldman Sachs ($75.00/share) supported the views that Steinberg did not overpay for his shares and that the shares might be worth considerably more than his cost. The disparity among the valuations existed simply because Disney was worth one thing on a business-as-usual basis and something much higher if restructured.

      Duties of Disney’s CEO and Board

      Consequences

      It is uncertain how employees or suppliers might fare after a takeover by Saul Steinberg, but his predilection to break the linkage between films and theme parks might lower the enjoyment for customers. On balance, greenmail to preserve the status quo might serve the interests of these groups. As for shareholders, circumstances might exist in which they would be better off after the greenmail payment even if they were discriminated against, their agents acted in self-interest, and the action was not freely taken. A decision involves weighing the evident costs of greenmail versus the potential benefits. One might argue that to place a price on discrimination or the loss of free choice is impossible and that managerial self-interest is always bad. Yet, in many ways every day, individuals submit to discrimination or loss of choice to enhance their own welfare. Furthermore, managerial self-interest is not harmful per se to shareholders; managerial and shareholder self-interest undoubtedly coincide in a wide range of decisions.

      The key question is whether Disney’s shareholders would receive any benefits to offset the costs of greenmail. The facts in the Disney case imply that management may have had an estimate of the intrinsic value of the firm that was materially higher than the ex ante share price or than a potential greenmail price per share. Under this circumstance, any repurchase of shares at a price less than intrinsic value will transfer wealth from the selling shareholders (i.e., the greenmailer) to the remaining public shareholders. The total wealth transferred depends on the difference between what the greenmailer (e.g., Steinberg) would have received had he bought and held versus what he actually received. If the wealth transfer is positive and material, Ron Miller might be justified in paying greenmail.

      Possible Engagement with the Other Side

      U.S. securities laws limit the extent to which the opposing sides in a hostile takeover contest can engage each other. Material developments mentioned in any conversation with the counterparty may need to be disclosed in public filings with the SEC. This constrains what can be said directly. But through emissaries, it was possible to negotiate a disengagement of the hostile action through a greenmail payment.

      Long-Term Validity of the Action

      Alternatives

      Miller had at least two alternatives to paying greenmail. One was to announce and execute a restructuring of the firm along the lines the raider would have to do to unlock latent value. This move would allow both the raider and the public to participate in the benefits. The second alternative was to offer to repurchase shares from the public instead of the greenmailer, as happened in the case of T. Boone Pickens’s attempted raid on Unocal. This would siphon cash to the public at the expense of the raider and enhance the freedom of choice of the public shareholder: He or she could elect to receive the greenmailer’s price per share or hold onto the shares in hopes of eventually receiving the intrinsic value per share. The decision to pay greenmail versus the alternatives ultimately depends on the wealth-creation/wealth-transfer effects each choice may have.

      Public Reaction

      The payment of greenmail is routinely condemned by analysts, investors, editorial writers, and public officials. Stock

Скачать книгу