Asset Allocation. William Kinlaw
Чтение книги онлайн.
Читать онлайн книгу Asset Allocation - William Kinlaw страница 27
In Equation 3.3,
Suppose the four securities are uncorrelated with each other. Then security selection would be more important than asset allocation because the asset classes would be less risky than the average risk of the securities they comprise, which results in less relative volatility between the asset classes than between the securities within each asset class. Moreover, as more securities are added, the asset class standard deviations decline further, which in turn further reduces the relative volatility between the asset classes. If, for example, security returns are uncorrelated and the securities are equally weighted, then the asset class standard deviation diminishes with the square root of the number of securities included. It is only when the correlation between asset classes A and B is substantially less than the correlation between the individual securities within the asset classes that the relative volatility between asset classes is greater than the relative volatility between securities. These relationships are illustrated in Table 3.1.
The upper left panel shows that relative volatility between asset classes is less than relative volatility between securities when they are all uncorrelated with one another. The upper right panel shows the same result when they all are equally correlated with one another. The lower left panel shows the asset class and security correlations that lead to convergence between relative volatilities. Finally, the lower right panel provides an example in which the relative volatility between asset classes is higher than it is between securities.
Determining Relative Importance by Simulation
The associations between standard deviation, correlation, and relative volatility are easy to illustrate when we consider only two asset classes each divided equally between only two securities. These associations become less clear when we consider several asset classes weighted differently among hundreds of securities with a wide range of volatilities and correlations. Under these real-world conditions, it is easier to resolve the question of relative importance by a simulation procedure known as bootstrapping.
Unlike Monte Carlo simulation, which draws random observations from a prespecified distribution, bootstrapping simulation draws random observations with replacement from empirical samples. Specifically, we generate thousands of random portfolios from a large universe of securities that vary only because of asset allocation or security selection. This allows us to observe the distribution of available returns associated with each investment decision as opposed to studying the actual performance of managed funds, which reflects the biases of their investors. Kritzman and Page (2002) conducted such an analysis for investment markets in five countries: Australia, Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States based on returns from 1988 to 2001. They showed that the dispersion around average performance arising from security selection was substantially greater than the dispersion arising from asset allocation in every country, and it was particularly large in the United States because the United States has a larger number of individual securities.5
L'Her and Plante (2006) refined the Kritzman and Page methodology to account for the relative capitalization of securities, and they also included a broader set of asset classes. Their analysis showed asset allocation and security selection to be approximately equally important – still a far different result from the conclusion of Brinson, Hood, and Beebower.
THE SAMUELSON DICTUM
We hope we have convinced you that asset allocation does not determine 94% of performance, and that contrary to this assumption, security selection has equal, if not greater, potential to affect the distribution of returns. Does it follow, therefore, that investors should focus more effort on security selection than asset allocation? Not at all. Paul A. Samuelson put forth the argument that investment markets are microefficient and macroinefficient, which implies that investors are more likely to succeed by engaging in asset allocation than in security selection. He argued that if an individual security is mispriced, a smart investor will notice and trade to exploit the mispricing, and by doing so will correct the mispricing. Therefore, opportunities to exploit the mispricing of individual securities are fleeting. However, if an aggregation of individual securities, such as an asset class, is mispriced, a smart investor will detect the mispricing and trade to exploit the mispricing. But one smart investor, or even several, would not have the scale to revalue an entire asset class. The mispricing of an asset class will likely persist until an exogenous shock jolts many investors, smart or not, to act in concert and thereby revalue the asset class. Thus, asset class mispricing endures sufficiently long to allow investors to profit from it.6
THE BOTTOM LINE
The notion that asset allocation is more important than security selection is based on a flawed analysis that failed to account for what an investor would do as an alternative to investing in the current portfolio. Also, many studies show asset allocation to be more important than security selection because they conflate investment choice with investment opportunity. If we correct for these two flaws, we find that security selection is at least as important, if not more important, than asset allocation. It does not follow, though, that investors should devote more resources to security selection than asset allocation, because, as argued by Paul Samuelson, it is easier to be successful at asset allocation than security selection. The bottom line is that asset allocation is very important, but not for the reasons put forth by Brinson, Hood, and Beebower.
RELATED