Richard Titmuss. Stewart, John

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Richard Titmuss - Stewart, John страница 7

Richard Titmuss - Stewart, John

Скачать книгу

Merton, that ‘in thinking about the subject of social policy research’ he had been stimulated by one of Merton’s papers.19 Published in 1949, this had discussed the extent to which social science could, and should, influence policy. In a passage which may have especially appealed to Titmuss, Merton argued that the ‘higher the social standing of a discipline, the more likely it will be to recruit able talents, the greater its measure of financial support, and the greater its actual accomplishments’.20 By the time of Titmuss’s correspondence with Merton, 1957, he had recruited ‘talents’ such as Abel-Smith, was actively pursuing research funding, and had already made a difference to policy making by way of, most notably, the Guillebaud Committee’s enquiry into NHS finances.

      These selected extracts scarcely do justice to Reisman’s text. But they do raise analytical points, some with which the present author would agree, others not. That about war and welfare, for example, is well made, and contains significant elements of truth, while being more complex than Reisman allows. And it is certainly true that Titmuss was a ‘committed communitarian’. However, he was also committed to defending individual rights, and individual choice. Similarly, that Titmuss was an ‘English author’ is unarguable, although again something which can be further developed. As we shall see, Titmuss can be seen as belonging to a very English, radical, tradition. This is not to say, though, that he did not engage with welfare policies in other countries. Equally, a case can be made that Titmuss’s work has not always been fully understood, and he was certainly an unusual figure in post-war British academic life. But was he really an ‘outsider’? It can be argued that he was, by his death, an ‘Establishment’ figure, although again this is not straightforward. Titmuss’s attitude to universalism, and discretion, meanwhile, was rather more complicated than is conventionally claimed, as was his attitude to voluntarism. And while it is true that Titmuss did not produce a work synthesising his approach to welfare, it is debatable whether he nonetheless produced an ‘intellectual map’, or at least one capable of rebuffing the increasingly demanding claims of neo-liberalism. However, and as Reisman implies, Titmuss’s angular, and holistic, approach did provide him with original insights. So Reisman offers an important platform for our understanding of Titmuss; but more can be said.

Скачать книгу