Mineral Resource Economy 2. Группа авторов

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Mineral Resource Economy 2 - Группа авторов страница 7

Mineral Resource Economy 2 - Группа авторов

Скачать книгу

extraction do not consume fewer resources to support the way of life of their inhabitants – quite the contrary. The comparison of the United States and Japan presents a counter-example of lifestyle moderation through proximity to mines. If one follows the assertion described above, Japan, which has not been a major mining country since the late 19th century, should consume more material per capita than the United States, Canada or Australia, which are, on the contrary, major mining producers. However, the exact opposite is true. In 2015, Japan had a material footprint of 23 tons per capita compared to 30, 34 and 42 tons, respectively, for the three mining countries (UNEP 2016). It could be contested that these three mining countries are much less dense than Japan, which implies more consumption for the construction and maintenance of infrastructure. This is true, but does not the latter country better reflect the case of European countries? The facts are stubborn, because a study published by the PNAS (Wiedmann et al. 2015) shows, through a statistical analysis of 137 countries and controlling for land density, that the volume of mining per capita is positively correlated with the material footprint per capita and domestic consumption per capita. In other words, countries that extract more minerals and resources on their territory also consume more materials to sustain the lifestyles of their citizens (the study also shows this for the subset of metals);

      – This naturally brings us to the fourth point. We must stop perceiving the energy transition as a supply problem that can only be solved by greater use of renewable energies (even if we do not disqualify the latter). With the exception of specific and local issues (such as chlorofluorocarbons for the hole in the ozone layer), supply-side policies alone have never succeeded in solving our global environmental problems (Dinda 2004), most of the time substituting one problem for another. It is also necessary to look at demand to cut off the pressure transfers downstream. Also, in the case of the upcoming energy transition, we must allow ourselves energy efficiency solutions and, above all, achieve greater sobriety.

      In a more macroeconomic perspective, Thierry Lefèvre (Chapter 6) develops in his contribution the questions related to the possibility of decoupling GDP and natural resources. This question of decoupling is complex and today mobilizes a large number of researchers, particularly within the United Nations Environment Programme’s (UNEP) International Resource Panel (IRP). The question of decoupling obviously refers to the tool of material efficiency, which aims to create more with less. By increasing the material productivity of our activities, we could gain in both ways: by continuing to increase GDP, while reducing our consumption of resources and the impacts left in its wake. This postulate of dematerializing the economy is an old one, notably through the concept of ephemeralization evoked by Philippe Bihouix (2019) in his latest book. We also come across it under the terms of decoupling, delinking or via the material Kuznets curve. But here again, the practical application shows poor results. Most of the time, decoupling is well below the scale effect of population and GDP per capita growth. On this point, the researcher’s contribution somewhat dashes our expectations by showing that the material footprint of most industrialized countries has grown over time.

      Another form of leverage is deemed as highly promising, that of recycling. Alain Geldron’s very comprehensive contribution (Chapter 7) on the subject of metal recycling appears enlightening from several points of view. First of all, far from the sometimes blissful optimism shown by the environmental press on urban mining and the circular economy, there is a wide gap between the discourse and the empirical facts: recycling rates are still far from circularity for base metals, and are even almost zero for minor metals. Indeed, there are several fundamental differences between the extractive metal economy and the metal recycling economy, which explain why we cannot switch from one to the other without major adjustments.

      First of all, the returns to scale derived from the size of the stakeholders and the volume of deposits are quite different between the two activities, clearly contributing to the domination of the first over the second. Moreover, the share of the informal sector is still very significant in the recycling economy, whereas it remains very marginal in the extractive economy, at least when we look at the volumes supplied. Second, the qualities of the materials from primary and secondary deposits differ considerably (Fizaine 2020), again with a marked

Скачать книгу