Competitive Advantage in Investing. Steven Abrahams

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Competitive Advantage in Investing - Steven Abrahams страница 17

Competitive Advantage in Investing - Steven Abrahams

Скачать книгу

      When investors followed Jensen's lead and tested CAPM they found that not only did αi have a value other than zero but also it followed a surprising but reliable pattern: images had a positive value when images is low and a negative value when images is high. In other words, more stable assets had a better return than predicted by CAPM and more volatile assets had a worse return. The capital markets line in the real world was flatter than predicted by theory.

      Higher beta investments still showed higher returns, but the flatness of the observed capital markets line suggested that CAPM alone might not explain it. The theory had a mysterious flaw.

Graph depicting how the average annualized monthly returns vary in their beta, and realized returns are too flat compared to the predictions of CAPM.

      Note: Average annualized monthly return versus beta for value-weight portfolios formed on prior beta, 1928–2003.

      Source: From Fama and French (2004).

      Starting in the late 1970s, studies of investment returns started making the case that factors other than expected return premium explained asset returns. A study by Sanjay Basu showed that earnings-to-price ratios added to the ability of CAPM to predict stock returns, with high earnings-to-price equities outperforming low (Basu, 1977). A study by Rolf Banz a few years later showed that market capitalization helped, too, with smaller market capitalizations performing better than predicted by CAPM (Banz, 1981). Laxmi Bhandari followed this lead and by the end of the 1980s found that debt-to-equity ratios helped CAPM explain returns, with high debt-to-equity performing better than predicted by beta alone (Bhandari, 1988). And other researchers found that high book-to-market equities also performed better than predicted by beta (Stattman, 1980; Rosenberg, Reid, and Lanstein, 1985).

      Fama and French fit the elements of their approach together in a single statement:

equation

      Fama and French point out that the average annual excess return of the market portfolio over the riskless rate from 1927 to 2003 was 8.3%. The average difference in return between small and large stocks, however, was 3.6%, and the average difference between high and low book-to-market stocks was 5.0%. They also put their approach to the same test that Jensen applied to CAPM:

equation

      In this test, if Fama and French's model described the world well, the value of αi also should be zero. Fama and French have broadly found that this approach does leave a value of αi about zero. Work by other researchers has found similar results (see, for example, Loughran and Ritter, 1995; Mitchell and Stafford, 2000). Studies of performance in mutual funds have also found that Fama and French's factors explain performance better than a simple CAPM approach (Carhart, 1997). Beyond the academic, investment firms such as Dimensional Advisors and AQR have built substantial businesses on Fama and French's observation, running portfolios that use these factors to try to outperform broad market benchmarks.

      In addition to Fama and French, other work has found more factors that seem to sway asset returns. Jegadeesh and Titman have found that returns seem to depend on a sort of momentum (Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993). Stocks that do better than the market over the most recent three or 12 months tend to continue doing well over the next few months, and stocks that do poorly continue doing poorly. Performance seems to persist and shape returns beyond even the factors that Fama and French describe. The list of influences on asset return grows.

      At the same time that both theorists and practitioners embraced CAPM and began to see its shortcomings, intriguing explanations and steps in new directions began to emerge.

      Both the flatness of returns relative to Sharpe's CAPM predictions and the influence on returns of factors beyond beta have led other analysts to argue that structural aspects of markets—not addressed by CAPM—lead to these results. In fact, Fischer Black, who spent years immersed in theory at the University of Chicago and years immersed in markets at Goldman Sachs, notes this possibility (Black, 1993):

      Another reason for a flatter line is restricted borrowing. Margin requirements, borrowing rates that are higher than lending rates, and limited deductibility of interest costs all tend to make the line flatter. Those who can't borrow at good rates bid up the prices of high-beta stocks instead.

      Yet another reason for a flatter line, I believe, is investor psychology, in particular “reluctance to borrow,” even when the rules allow it and the rates are good.

Скачать книгу