Competitive Advantage in Investing. Steven Abrahams

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Competitive Advantage in Investing - Steven Abrahams страница 18

Competitive Advantage in Investing - Steven Abrahams

Скачать книгу

Many people seem to dislike the idea of borrowing or the trading needed to adjust borrowing amounts to the values of their securities portfolios. (p. 38)

      Andrea Frazzini and Lasse Pedersen also argue that limits to investors' ability to leverage or deleverage positions in the market basket explain some of the flatness in realized returns (Frazzini and Pedersen, 2012):

      For instance, individual investors and pension funds may not be able to use any leverage, banks face regulatory capital constraints, and hedge funds must satisfy their margin requirements. However, an investor can gain substantial market exposure without using outright leverage by buying options, leveraged ETFs, or other securities that embed the leverage. In fact, many of these securities are designed precisely to provide embedded leverage. (p. 1)

      Cliff Asness and Tobias Moskowitz have joined Lasse Pedersen, all affiliated at some point in their careers with the University of Chicago and the asset manager AQR, to extend the search for factors that influence value on a wide range of assets (Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen, 2013). They find evidence for a value factor, such as book-to-market for equities and similar measures for other assets, and evidence for a momentum factor, linking recent and future performance. And they find evidence for value and momentum in a wide range of settings: in the US, UK, European, and Japanese equity markets; in equity index futures, government bonds, currencies, and commodity futures. The search across markets enables Asness and his colleagues to look at the correlations among these strategies in otherwise unrelated markets, and they find returns on value strategies positively correlated with value strategies across markets, momentum strategies similarly correlated across markets, and value and momentum negatively correlated within and across markets. That raises the issue of a potential common cause. They find modest links to macroeconomic variables such as business cycle, consumption, and default. They find more evidence of a common link through liquidity, particularly the availability and cost of funding, although it only explains a small part of the return premium.

      The work that finds factors other than beta that help explain asset performance draws criticism from theorists who argue that the factors only represent ad hoc ways to capture historical patterns of return, and that the factors do not represent separate, systemic, and undiversifiable sources of risk. But Fama and French (2004) argue that additional factors still challenge CAPM if they are well diversified and capture aspects of performance that the market portfolio alone misses. This is less of a concern for practitioners.

      Of more concern for practitioners is the potential errors made by applying a Sharpe-Linter or Black CAPM. Practitioners estimating a fair value of equity stand to get it wrong, at least by more elaborate factor models, for companies at the extremes of book-to-market or small-to-large. And investors trying to evaluate investment managers might attribute too much portfolio return to manager skill in portfolios stocked with low book-to-market or small equities.

      CAPM remains, as Fama and French acknowledge, “a theoretical tour de force” (Fama and French, 2004). If CAPM consistently misses important features of asset returns, however, then the hunt starts either for better tests of the theory or for better theories. It is in the latter direction that we go next.

      A New Focus on Leverage

      The work of Harry Markowitz highlights the trade-off between risk and reward and the power of diversification. Sharpe and others then argue heroically that all investors should hold some combination of cash and a market portfolio. Markowitz's emphasis on risk and reward and diversification remains as powerful and practical today as it did when he first published his seminal paper. Sharpe's CAPM, however, although offering an appealing elegance, has proven a poor explanation of investment returns in practice. Asset prices clearly depend on more than broad exposure to market risk. And the very work that tested CAPM ends up planting the seeds of a more nuanced approach.

Graph depicting how CAPM assumes that investors can borrow without limit at the riskless rate and leverage the market portfolio into expected returns well above an unleveraged portfolio of risky assets.

      Rather than a complete absence of riskless borrowing, a limit on leverage is a much more realistic starting point. Limits to borrowing show up routinely. Federal regulators have long put limits on individuals' ability to borrow and buy stocks. Current US securities regulations limit individuals to borrowing $0.50 for every $1 of market value in a stock portfolio. Banks and insurers have limits on the amount they can borrow to buy loans and securities. Laws establishing mutual funds impose limits to leverage. Hedge funds face practical limits to leverage. In fact, investors with unlimited access to efficient leverage are exceedingly hard if not impossible

Скачать книгу