Value. Frederick Harry Pitts

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Value - Frederick Harry Pitts страница 7

Value - Frederick Harry Pitts

Скачать книгу

art’, championing a return to the ‘real economy’ long before it became fashionable to do so – indeed, around the time when such a distinction was still halfway plausible.

      Assessing the contributions of Boisguillebert and others, Marx attributes to the physiocrats a laudable desire to investigate surplus value and relate it to labour-time, but without having first given thought to the form of value itself. In this way, the physiocrats were guilty of ‘discussing a complex form of the problem without having solved its elementary form’. This led to them ‘confusing the labour which is materialised in the exchange-value of commodities and measured in time units with the direct physical activity of individuals’.14

      Moreover, whilst acknowledging the stratification of society necessary to the system of commodity production, and recognizing the ‘significance of labour’ in his theory of production costs, Smith incorporated labour only insofar as it cast producers as simple owners of commodities who enter the marketplace eager to exchange commodified portions of their own embodied, objectified labour with others. This process was not contextualized within capitalist society, but seen as an expression of ‘direct barter, the spontaneous form of exchange’ intrinsic to the human experience.22 In this ahistorical and asocial fashion, Smith’s analysis centred on the commodity as its key principle, labour’s significance relating only to its role in commodity production and exchange. Hence, it is not as simple as saying a labour ‘substance’ determines value in exchange, but rather there is a two-way process in which the one depends upon the other. This introduces a profound ambivalence in Smith’s value theory.23 The value of a commodity expresses the labour embodied in it, whilst at the same time positing the amount of labour its production commands from the labour marketplace – an apparent exchange of equivalent amounts of objectified labour Smith took at face value. Lacking an effective mechanism for explaining the ‘determining social matrix’ behind this state of affairs, Smith’s approach was ‘confused’ and ‘tautological’, and ultimately unsuccessful in its attempt to ‘overcome the problematic’ of value.24 It was left to Marx to confront capitalist society as the ‘immense collection of commodities’ Smith describes, and to uncover the secret of labour power concealed within.25

      ****

      What Ricardo highlights is the analytical potential of the cost-of-production approach once its circularity is broken. The cost-of-production approach posits no metaphysical abstract order behind value; its virtue is that it takes at face value the price of inputs and relates them to the value of their output. By leaving open the huge logical blindspot of how the inputs acquire their value to begin with, this perspective leaves the field free for inquiries into the constitution of the value of inputs through historical, social, political and ethical processes and modes of contestation, including hierarchies, tastes, laws and customs. The value of the cost-of-production approach, therefore, lies in its circumvention of abstract inquiry in order to root value in a ‘skeptical empiricism that looks no farther than those social relationships of power, morality, and perhaps even reason as the basis on which social continuity is grounded and persists’.28

Скачать книгу