The Power In The Land. Fred Harrison

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison страница 8

Автор:
Серия:
Издательство:
The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison

Скачать книгу

the race for wealth, and honours, and preferments, he may run as hard as he can, and strain every nerve and muscle, in order to outstrip all his competitors. But if he should justle, or throw down any of them, the indulgence of the spectators is entirely at an end. It is a violation of fair play, which they cannot admit of.13

      The equal opportunity for everyone to strive as hard as he or she could, and be rewarded accordingly, in a growing economy which ensured the employment of all, was an intrinsic part of his vision of the good life. So long as all the participants played the game fairly, according to the rules, all would be well. But what if the rules handicapped some of the players in such a way that there was no fair way in which they could either win the race or even reach the finishing line ? What if the rules prevented some of the would-be participants from even joining the game ? These were critical questions to which Smith should have addressed himself, for the structure of property rights, and in particular the monopoly of land, biased the system against some of the players.

      Like all other men? To which group in the economy was he referring? He advanced evidence that capitalists and labourers earned their incomes, but was not able to offer any justification for the reapings of the land monopolists; nor could he. So he sought to justify the role of the landlords by claiming that their exactions were the normal psychological failings of all men. He was unwilling to admit that the unwarranted division of income — the result of the exercise of that monopoly power for which he condemned the mercantilists — would disrupt competition.

      Were the tools available to enable Smith to propose the means by which the frictions in the market system could be eliminated, so that the system could operate closer to its theoretical ideal ? Before defining an answer, we need to look at the dynamics of the land market.

      Land as a factor of production has certain unique qualities. For practical purposes, its supply is fixed, at the local level. Ultimately, the world is a closed economy. To control land, therefore, is to wield total power. But there is a more fundamental characteristic which differentiates land from capital and labour: the life span of people and machines is finite; the life of a plot of land is infinite. This has an important consequence for an economy relying simultaneously on competition and co-operation. Land monopolists can — and do — refuse to play the game whenever they choose. If they are not satisfied with the price that they are offered for their land, they can withdraw it from use without fear. They know that the value of the land is constantly appreciating, and that the rental revenue they forego today will be recouped in a few years through an increase in the value of the land (which is the capitalisation of a given number of years’ revenue). People, on the other hand, cannot play the game for any length of time. If they withdraw their labour they starve; and there is no way in which their lost wages can be recovered. Similarly with capital. If the owners withdraw machines, these rot away; the rate of depreciation can be slowed down, but only at the expense of maintaining them while they are idle.

      There is only one free market solution to the partial paralysis which is otherwise present in the industrial system: a fiscal obligation on the possession of land. A tax levied on the market value of all land would constitute a continuous pressure on the possessors, a cost analagous to that on the capitalist who must maintain his machines while they are idle. If the tax was levied at a high enough rate, the effect would be immediate. Either people would use the land to best effect, or, since they could not carry the tax liability for long while the land was not yielding an income, they would have to relinquish it to others. The tax on land values, then, would induce those who possessed land to play the game of competition and co-operation. They could not withdraw from participation and expect to take the land with them. Within this fiscal framework the ‘invisible hand’ would be restored to health and would be capable of handling, in an orderly way, the multiplicity of problems with which it is presented by a community of people with scarce resources, limitless wants and a diversity of tastes.

Скачать книгу