The Power In The Land. Fred Harrison

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison страница 12

Автор:
Серия:
Издательство:
The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison

Скачать книгу

the Western world, but their impact cannot be tracked because of the dearth of information on which analytical evaluations have to be based. This was the major finding of research in 1982 by a City of London stockbroker, Christopher Walls, who discovered the alarming extent of our ignorance when he tried to investigate institutional investment in property.

      The topic is of crucial importance for our understanding not only of real estate, but also because of the implications for economic regeneration: real estate constitutes to a large extent the credit lending base for UK industry. And in 1982 the institutions invested £2bn. in property, hardly a penny- pinching operation of no concern to people in the rest of the economy.

      The study by Walls should have been a routine exercise for an investment advisor, but it rapidly turned into an impossible task. He was confronted with ‘misleading and inaccurate information’; the quality of the official and unofficial statistics was abysmal; the yields from prime property were misrepresented by the simple expedient of shifting the definition of what constituted prime property; and there was no standard practice for declaring the value of assets.

      The indifference towards the influence of land monopoly on the industrial economy is only too apparent; this indifference actually masks a positive discrimination in favour of the interests of the landed class.

      An identical effect on social welfare is achieved by the decisions made by individual land monopolists. An example from the urban sector neatly illustrates how speculation restricts economic growth.

      Economists traditionally assume that the ceiling on output is set by the rate of growth of population, technical progress and the accumulation of capital; land monopoly is ignored as a brake on the economy. At a London meeting of the Underground Railway Group in February 1927, Lord Ashfield complained bitterly that the Edgware extension of the London Electric Railway had continued to develop its traffic ‘at a slower rate than was anticipated’. Why? He offered an explanation: land speculation at the Edgware terminal had forced up prices to a level which restricted purchases. ‘This is an evil which besets all railway enterprise,’ he declared, and he proposed as a remedy ‘some means by which the increment in the value of the land could be appropriated to pay some share of the enormous cost attending the construction of Underground Railways in Greater London’.

      The following year, Lord Ashfield’s complaint was investigated by the Liberal Party’s Industrial Inquiry, the committee of which included Lloyd George and John Maynard Keynes. They reported:

      This was a familiar story: public expenditure on improved transportation — to cut the costs of travel and extend the range of living and working environments — pushed up land values. This, in itself, is not a weakness of the economic system, provided that the price of land was not forced above the economic surplus — the real rental value of land proportionate to the current output of wealth. Under the present arrangements, however, not only are the socially-created increases in land values privately appropriated, but the monopolistic structure of the land market encourages speculators to force up their asking prices to speculative levels, consequently retarding the process of capital formation and economic growth.

      The vital conclusions ought to be obvious, but they have been ignored. Where capitalists cut costs and increase efficiency, land monopolists serve their interests best by increasing costs and decreasing overall efficiency. Where capitalism raises consumer satisfaction by extending the range of goods and services at lower prices, land monopoly restricts the choice and raises prices. This outcome arises inevitably from the simple truth that the pursuit of speculative rents can reward the monopolists only by curtailing general welfare.

      But vacant sites are not the only manifestation of a malfunctioning land market. Monopoly can produce economic inefficiency even when owners use their land. For monopoly enables landowners to conceal entrepreneurial inefficiency. If, for instance, the performance of a firm is inadequate to pay wages at the ruling rates, interest on capital investment and rent to land, the proprietors can delude themselves by foregoing the economic rent which they ought, as a bookkeeping exercise, to impute to themselves as land- owners. What usually happens is that they pay wages and interest, and disregard rental income. While this situation may be tolerable to the owner- occupying entrepreneurs, resources are not being used to their best advantage

Скачать книгу