The Political Economy of the BRICS Countries. Группа авторов

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу The Political Economy of the BRICS Countries - Группа авторов страница 11

The Political Economy of the BRICS Countries - Группа авторов

Скачать книгу

A. and D. Treisman (2015). “A normal country: Russia after communism”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1): 151–174.

      Studwell, J. (2013). How Asia Works. Success and failure in the world’s most dynamic region, New York: Grove Press.

      Stuenkel, O. (2014). “Emerging powers and status: The case of the first BRICs summit”, Asian Perspectives, 38: 89–109.

      Sweetwood, D. M. (2002). “Is Brazil’s economy coming back to life”, Multinational Business Review, 10(1): 54–59.

      Triesman, D. (2016). “Russia’s billionaires”. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 106(5): 236–241.

      Turaga, R. M. R., M. Chakrabarti, M. Chatterjee, S. Jolad, Ka Vaijayanti and M. S. Sriram (2018). “State of inclusive growth in India: Some perspectives”, Vikalpa, 43(1): 24–46.

      Wedeman, A. (2004). “The intensification of corruption in China”, The China Quarterly, 180(12): 895–921.

      Wei, Y. D. (1999). “Regional inequality in China”, Progress in Human Geography, 23(1): 45–59.

      Wen, W. and G. Zhaoyu (2017). “10 myths about Brics debunked”, Financial Times, September 1.

      Wilkin, P. (2008). “Global communication and political culture in the semi-periphery: The rise of the Globo corporation”, Review of International Studies, 34: 93–113.

      Wohlforth, W. C. (2001). “The Russian-Soviet empire: A test of neorealism”, Review of International Studies, 27: 213–235.

      World Economic Forum (2017). The Inclusive Growth and Development Report, Geneva: World Economic Forum.

      World Inequality Lab (2018). World Inequality Report, Paris: World Inequality Lab.

      Yao, S. and L. Zhu (1998). “Understanding income inequality in China: A multi-angle perspective”, Economics of Planning, 31: 133–150.

      Zakaria, F. (1992). “Realism and domestic politics: A review essay”, International Security, 17(1): 177–198.

      Zhuravskaya, E. (2007). “Whither Russia? A review of Andrei Shleifer’s a normal country”, Journal of Economic Literature, XLVI: 127–146.

      Ziegler, C. E. (2014). “Russia in Central Asia: The dynamics of great-power politics in a volatile region”, Asian Perspectives, 38: 589–617.

      CHAPTER 2

      Future of BRICS as an Economic Block: Does Macroeconomic Heterogeneity and Unshared Political Mandate Stand in Its Way?

      Partha Ray

       Economics Group, Indian Institute of Management Calcutta, Kolkata, India

      Introduction

      Economic blocks are normally the outcome of certain historical and political process.1 One can discern the birth of G7 in the pre-Cold War days when France, Italy, Japan, the UK, the US, and West Germany formed the Group of Six in 1975 and Canada joined the following year. Effectively, it emerged as a forum for the non-Communist powers to address pressing economic concerns such as inflation and the recession sparked by the OPEC oil crisis and dominated by Cold War politics. Or take the case of the euro area, which was born in the aftermath of the Cold War perhaps motivated by a search to question the hegemony of the US dollar. From that standpoint the genesis of the BRIC block, having emanated from the research report of a global investment bank, was indeed unique.

      Initially the focus of the analysis was confined to four economies, viz., Brazil, Russia, India, and China — thus giving birth to the acronym of ‘BRIC’ economies. In projecting future GDP trends in BRIC economies, the Goldman Sachs 2001 report considered a number of scenarios.2 The report arrived at a startling result: “Over the next 10 years, the weight of the BRICs and especially China in world GDP will grow, raising important issues about the global economic impact of fiscal and monetary policy in the BRICs” (Goldman Sachs, 2001). In particular, in all four scenarios, the relative weight of the BRICs rises from 8.0% at present (in current USD) to 14.2%, or from 23.3% to 27.0%, converting at purchasing power parity (PPP). Subsequently, in a sequel to the original report, Goldman Sachs argued: “If things go right, the BRICs could become a very important source of new global spending in the not too distant future. … India’s economy, for instance, could be larger than Japan’s by 2032, and China’s larger than the US by 2041 (and larger than everyone else as early as 2016). The BRICs economies taken together could be larger than the G6 by 2039” (Goldman Sachs, 2003). Such discussion has been the subject of a number of academic studies as well.3

      More recently, following the report from the Finance Ministers at the fifth BRICS summit in Durban (2013), the BRICS leaders signed the Agreement establishing the New Development Bank (NDB) (formerly referred to as the BRICS Development Bank) which is expected to, ‘strengthen cooperation among BRICS and will supplement the efforts of multilateral and regional financial institutions for global development, thus contributing to collective commitments for achieving the goal of strong, sustainable and balanced growth’.

      Are all these developments pointers toward the emergence of BRICS as a new kid on the global economic power block? Are these five countries going to pose a threat to G7 economies in the years to come? This chapter argues that there are ample dampeners in the way of this expectation turning out to be true. While such a possible outcome could be reasoned out using differing viewpoints, viz., economic, social, or political, my focus here is somewhat limited. In particular, I will argue that the differences in macroeconomic structure and economic policies could make the BRICS block (and not necessarily individual countries) fragile with little cohesion.

      The

Скачать книгу