Innovation Economics, Engineering and Management Handbook 1. Группа авторов

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Innovation Economics, Engineering and Management Handbook 1 - Группа авторов страница 15

Innovation Economics, Engineering and Management Handbook 1 - Группа авторов

Скачать книгу

of the major limitations of this indicator is that R&D appears to be mainly focused on science and technology and has difficulty capturing the expenditure incurred to bring about other forms of innovation, whether organizational or commercial. The services that make up an important part of the new solutions offered by companies are better evaluated by marketing expenses, which are not included in the R&D measurement. As a result, the expenditures made by small firms (which rarely employ researchers) to innovate organizationally or commercially are poorly understood and, therefore, not considered as being very innovative.

      A patent is an industrial property title granted to an inventor for a period of 20 years, often used as an indicator of results and innovation performance. It has the advantage of being an available and reliable indicator, whose databases are public. Worldwide patent registration statistics show a strong growth in patent registrations from the 1970s onwards. Innovators around the world filed some 3.3 million patent applications in 2018, an increase of 5.2% for the ninth consecutive year of growth. At that time, approximately 14 million patents were in force worldwide. The largest numbers of patents in force were registered in the United States (3.1 million), China (2.4 million) and Japan (2.1 million) (WIPO 2019).

      However, as an indicator of innovation, the patent also suffers from many limitations. On the one hand, it only measures registered “inventions”, thus leaving aside all other possible forms of innovation. On the other hand, many inventions are not patented, especially if they do not meet the criteria of novelty, inventive step and industrial application. An invention that is useful, but not innovative (so if it is already part of the state of the art, in other words everything that has been made public at the filing date), will not normally be able to pass the stage of the research report carried out by the industrial property institute. A registered patent does not always result in an innovation, i.e. a new product launched on the market or a new process integrated into the production process. Many patented inventions remain unexploited, often for strategic reasons. For example, some patents are intended to deceive competitors about the technological trajectories followed. Sleeping patents are also very common. In this case, they are not exploited because the profit prospects are lower than the costs of bringing them to market. The company holding the patent may not have the resources necessary to exploit the invention or may prefer to wait for the previous invention to become fully profitable before launching a new one (in this case, one can speak of “technological Malthusianism”).

      Innovation indicators are not limited to these two; they also include the number of researchers, scientific publications, amounts devoted to financing innovative firms (venture capital), registrations of other intellectual property titles (trademarks, designs), revenue generated by innovative firms, diffusion of key technologies, etc. A better understanding of the innovation process leads not to limiting research to traditional indicators but to refining the evaluation of innovation efforts and performance by using other indicators. For example, at the firm level, statisticians (see OECD 2019) seek to better measure intangible investments that are not R&D (such as software and databases), or the interactions that firms develop with other firms or institutions. At the country level, indicator scoreboard and summary indicators are being developed to quantify innovation.

      In Europe, the European Union Innovation Scoreboard (created in 2001) provides a synthetic indicator for ranking countries according to their innovation performance. Four categories of countries are defined: modest innovators, moderate innovators, notable innovators and innovation champions. The results for 2019 were as follows.

      Sweden, Finland, Denmark and the Netherlands appeared to be the leaders in innovation, positioning themselves well above the European average. Notable innovators included the following countries: Luxembourg, Belgium, the United Kingdom, Germany, Austria, Ireland, France and Estonia. Their results were slightly above (or close to) the European average. The performance of moderate innovators was between 50% and 90% of the European average. This category included many countries in Eastern and Southern Europe, such as Portugal, Czech Republic, Slovenia, Cyprus, Malta, Italy, Spain, Greece, Lithuania, Slovakia, Hungary, Latvia, Poland and Croatia. Finally, the modest innovators, Romania and Bulgaria, had a performance below 50% of the European average.

      This synthetic indicator – the Summary Innovation Index – is based on four broad categories of indicators and 10 dimensions of innovation. The “framework conditions” take into account the essential factors of innovation performance, and this category includes human resources, the attractiveness of the research system and the environment conducive to innovation. “Investments” measures public and private investment in innovation. “Innovation activities” seeks to measure the efforts made by firms, distinguishing between the characteristics of innovators, networks and intellectual assets. Finally, the “Impacts” category considers impacts on employment and sales. In total, the composite indicator is constructed from 27 indicators.

      Figure 1.1. Member countries' innovation performance (source: European Innovation Scoreboard 2019). For a color version of this figure, see www.iste.co.uk/uzunidis/innovation1.zip

      While Schumpeter was the first economist to develop an innovation theory, he also designated the entrepreneur as the economic agent who achieves “new combinations of production factors” (Boutillier and Uzunidis 2016). Entrepreneurial economics certainly did not begin with Schumpeter. As early as the 18th century, the entrepreneur was already attracting the attention of economists, but more to emphasize their ability to take commercial risks (the merchant) than to design and manufacture new products (the industrialist) (Cantillon 1755). The figure of the “projector” was generally devalued because his extravagant projects ran the risk of a general crisis, harmful to all, according to A. Smith (1759, 1776).

      As pointed out above, technical progress did not appear in the 18th century. It is a permanent feature of human societies. During the 18th century, however, a twofold evolution can be observed. On the one hand, technical progress is intrinsically linked to the market and gives rise either to the production of new consumer goods intended for the final consumer or to the production of machines for companies that automate production processes. On the other hand, there is a separation between science

Скачать книгу