Innovation Economics, Engineering and Management Handbook 1. Группа авторов
Чтение книги онлайн.
Читать онлайн книгу Innovation Economics, Engineering and Management Handbook 1 - Группа авторов страница 16
Whereas until the 18th century, the entrepreneur was essentially a merchant and, in this sense, could be dependent on a difference between sale and purchase prices (Landes et al. 2010). In the 19th century, the entrepreneur became an industrialist. Until this period, the field of technology was rather that of the craftsman (Zilsel 1942). This evolution did not take place without resistance nor social and political conflicts; machines were then qualified as job killers (Jarrige 2009). However, while many craftsmen disappeared, caught up in the big businesses that reduced them to the precarious condition of factory workers, others became entrepreneurs and created industrial empires, via the development of new technologies (electricity, mechanics, automobiles, telecommunications, aviation, etc.) (Perrin 2017).
The managerial company model (separation between ownership and management of capital) became a norm by the end of the 19th century, mainly in the United States and then in Western Europe. Schumpeter (2008), an attentive reader of Marx, detected in this evolution a major change in capitalism, which was becoming bureaucratized (see section 13.2). This observed disappearance of the entrepreneur marks the continuation of a process of division of labor between the manager (who manages the firm) and the shareholder (who finances it through the shares they buy). The entrepreneur, the driving force of the first Industrial Revolution, disappears to the benefit of a new institution, the managerial company.
In the years following the end of World War II, during the period of reconstruction, the economies of industrialized countries underwent an unprecedented transformation (Dockès 2020), taking advantage of new technologies and heavy investments developed during the war (automobiles, aviation, chemicals, nuclear, digital, IT, etc.). The entrepreneur was then seen as an endangered species, with the future belonging to the “technostructure” (Galbraith 1967) thanks to the “visible hand of managers” (Chandler 1977). This period of strong growth was based on the partnership between the large company and the labor society. The State then played a central role in financing scientific research and planning the economy, contributing to the development of managerial firms in highly capital-intensive sectors (steel, telecommunications, transport, energy, petrochemicals, etc.) (see section 13.5). The time had come for mass production and consumption. Gradually, this model was seized, leading to the “great turnaround” of the 1970s (Dockès 2020).
Big corporations entered a crisis period; the markets created by the innovations of the post-World War II period were saturated. Unemployment was rising sharply in the industrial countries. Large companies no longer generated enough jobs, and even drastically reduced their workforce in order to reduce their costs. From the end of the 1970s onwards, the creation of companies appeared as a means of public policy to reduce unemployment whatever the job seeker’s profile (women, young people, elderly people, immigrants, non-qualified people, etc.). The creation of a company then became a kind of injunction to designate this process of socio-economic transformation. Bringing the Schumpeterian entrepreneurial theory up to date, the injunction is not only about job creation (and first and foremost that of the entrepreneur), but also about innovation, which is more than ever necessary to strengthen the competitiveness of economies. The new entrepreneur must be an innovator like their peers and is an integral part of the national innovation system in a knowledge-based economy (see section 1.4). The entrepreneurial society (Audretsch 2007) gradually began taking over from the labor society.
The entrepreneur, who had been sidelined by the managerial company, then made a big comeback by developing new innovations. They act in the sense in which Say understood it, i.e. as an intermediary between the scientist and the worker. The scientist was no longer isolated in an obscure laboratory, as was imagined in the 18th and 19th centuries, but was part of the great scientific laboratories financed by States, often by the army (Isaacson 2015). Young entrepreneurs, poorly endowed with capital, but very imaginative and with a keen sense of business, created industrial empires, giving rise, for example, to what we now refer to as GAFAM (Google, Apple, Facebook, Amazon, Microsoft). The large firm did not disappear, therefore, but took on a new form, favoring subcontracting and cooperative relationships via open innovation (Chesbrough 2003), rather than the model of vertical integration which the managerial firm of the 1950s–1970s was based on, inspired by the legacy of the first Industrial Revolution. The firm has taken the form of a network firm, combining classical integration with multiple cooperative relationships with universities, other competing firms (coopetition), complementary firms (customers and suppliers), start-ups, communities and crowdsourcing (Laperche and Uzunidis 2019). The constitution and development of its knowledge capital (i.e. all the information and knowledge produced, accumulated and systematized by the company with the aim of innovating) is carried out collectively (Laperche 2017). The principle of open innovation offers innovative entrepreneurs, who have become start-uppers, the opportunity to develop cooperative relationships with large companies, as well as with research centers and universities (Audretsch and Link 2017), as put forward with the concept of the “triple helix” (Etzkowitz 2003).
How companies manage their innovation process is a key theme in innovation management. The work of Nonaka and his co-authors, for example, focuses on the genesis and circulation of knowledge in the organization. This is the SECI (socialization, externalization, combination, internalization) model (Nonaka and Takeushi 1995), where innovation in the organization emerges from the interaction between explicit and tacit knowledge, associated with a circulation of knowledge from the individual to the inter-organizational level. Similarly, the C-K theory (which stands for concept and knowledge) focuses on issues of creativity within design and provides further developments on the genesis of knowledge within organizations (Hatchuel and Weil 2009; Le Masson and Macmahon 2016).
This work on the production and dissemination of knowledge within organizations is part of resource theory. The authors place particular emphasis on the role of competencies (especially key competencies (Prahalad and Hamel 1990)) and capabilities in explaining the competitive advantage of firms. Capabilities develop new specific assets gathered in organizational routines, which are called “dynamic capabilities” by Teece et al. (1997). They refer to the “firm’s ability to integrate, build and reconfigure internal and external competencies to respond quickly to changes in the environment”. Among these dynamic capacities, the absorption capacity is central to the analysis of firms’ knowledge capital formation. Absorptive capacity was first defined by Cohen and Levinthal (1990) as the firm’s ability to recognize the value of new information, transform it into knowledge, assimilate it and apply it for business purposes. The firm is then open to its environment, and the management of multiple cooperative relationships is considered a “managerial innovation” (Mignon et al. 2020).
Universities have also transformed themselves to become entrepreneurial and play a more active role in innovation. The economic context, marked by a decline in public funding for research, is contributing to a radical metamorphosis in the work of the researcher who also becomes an entrepreneur, by creating a spin-off, or by filing patents, etc., responding to the injunctions of all up-and-coming entrepreneurs (Lanciano-Morandat 2019). It is also in universities, primarily in the United States, that major transformations are taking place. In the laboratories of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), hackers and makers are appearing who will also contribute to transforming production methods, with an entrepreneurial and creative approach.
The first hackers formed a closed club: they are distinguished by their technical prowess. Unlike the Fordist company, which was then dominant, they worked in a collaborative and horizontal way. Each could take the ideas of the other and improve them (Capdevila 2015). This principle was also developed with fablabs at the end of the 1990s, again at MIT (Morel and Le Roux 2016). The objective is to be able to “create anything and everything”. The experiment is bearing fruit. Students do not hesitate to hijack the machines to satisfy their needs. The principle of “Do It Yourself” then takes on its full meaning, even if some people date it back to the end of the 18th century (Berrebi-Hoffmann et al. 2018). The word “hacker” appeared in the mid-2000s (Anderson 2012), to designate a