Sustainable Futures. Raphael Kaplinsky

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Sustainable Futures - Raphael Kaplinsky страница 14

Sustainable Futures - Raphael  Kaplinsky

Скачать книгу

href="#ulink_cdcd407c-d6c8-5ad1-8127-7a2fd96311c6">Figure 2.4 Balance of payments: largest debtor and surplus economies, 1998–2019 ($m)

      Source: data from Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)

      This toxic combination of deindustrialization and free trade undermined the incentive to invest and reduced the rate of productivity and economic growth in the economies pursuing neo-liberal policy agendas. But, as we will see in the following chapter, it also contributed to growing inequality, the precarity of livelihoods and the rise of populist political leaders.

      Building factories and infrastructure requires a variety of inputs, including labour, material supplies and services. The production of these inputs generates incomes. Workers earn wages and salaries, and this cascades along the supply chain as suppliers require their own suppliers. But does this economic activity add up to the balancing of supply and demand? Are the incomes generated in all of the supply chains sufficient to consume what is being produced in the economy?

      Both of these factors were at play during the Great Depression in the 1930s. The Great Crash in the stock markets in 1929 plunged many consumers into debt. Unemployment grew rapidly, partly – as we will see in Chapter 5 – as a result of the introduction of labour-saving mass production technologies. And consumer confidence plummeted. Moreover, income inequality had grown rapidly during the 1920s and there were limits to how many luxury yachts, gold-plated watches and designer clothes an individual could consume. The combination of these developments resulted in a downward spiral in the major economies. As consumption fell, firms reduced their output or went out of business. This led to a reduction in the incomes required to consume what was being produced. Consumer confidence fell, further dampening the demand for the goods. And thus, the economy spiralled downwards.

      The challenge of managing consumption to balance production remained a critically important component of public and economic policy throughout the twentieth century, and has endured during the first two decades of the twenty-first century. As we will see in subsequent chapters, after World War 2, government expenditure played an important role in sustaining consumer demand. In the US, and then in Europe, there were massive investments in housing and in the infrastructure required to promote the growth of automobilization and suburbanization. In Europe, welfare programmes played a complementary role in sustaining consumption. Although these post-war welfare programmes were not rationalized in terms of their contribution to economic stability and growth, both directly (though benefit payments) and indirectly (as jobs were created in the public sector delivering welfare benefits) they played a critical role in bolstering consumption.

      But from the beginning of the 1980s, these well-tried structures for matching demand and supply in the economy were undermined by the introduction of neo-liberal economic policies. These were pioneered in the UK and the US – the Thatcher–Reagan revolution – and then replicated across the globe, sometimes as a result of national choice and, in other cases (notably in the developing world), as a result of pressure exerted by the US, the UK and the EU. Neo-liberalism sought to reduce the role of government and to reduce the ‘tax burden’. It promoted lower tax rates on higher incomes in order to ‘remove the disincentive to entrepreneurship and investment’. Simultaneously, the neo-liberal agenda attacked welfare payments on the basis that social security promoted the growth of a ‘work-shy’ labour force living off welfare. (The irony in this agenda was that, whilst it was argued that welfare support reduced the incentive of the poor to work, it was simultaneously argued that tax reduction would increase the incentive of the rich to work even harder!)

fig2-5

      Source: data from OECD

      This neo-liberal agenda undermined the capacity of governments to fund investments in infrastructure. Consequently, over the subsequent decades the deficit in infrastructure spending mushroomed in the high-income economies, particularly in the US and the UK. In the US, between 2003 and 2017, public expenditure on roads, bridges, water systems and other infrastructure fell by 8 per cent. In 1930 (even before Roosevelt’s New Deal Program investments in roads and dams), infrastructure investments were 4.2 per cent of GDP. In 2016, this ratio had fallen to 2.5 per cent. The American Society of Civil Engineers estimated that underinvestment in infrastructure between 2016 and 2025 would exceed 2 trillion dollars.2 The UK is in an even more parlous state with the share of infrastructure spending in GDP being even lower than that in the US.3

Скачать книгу