Sustainable Futures. Raphael Kaplinsky

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Sustainable Futures - Raphael Kaplinsky страница 17

Sustainable Futures - Raphael  Kaplinsky

Скачать книгу

US corporate debt rose from $439bn in 1980 to $3.1tn in 2007, before the Great Recession. Thereafter, it mushroomed to reach $14.15tn in 2019.10 US Federal Government debt also grew rapidly, from $879bn in 1980 to $9.5tn before the Great Recession, and to $22.8tn in 2019. US Federal debt owed to international and foreign parties rose from £492bn in 1990 to $2.4tn in 2007, and to $6.9tn in 2019.11 All of this spiralling debt, of course, predated the Covid-19 epidemic which hit the global economy in 2020, exacerbating each of these growing debt piles.

      These spiralling levels of household, corporate and government debt reflect the underwriting of consumption in the US, the UK and other high-income countries. For, as we saw above, the levels of investment in productive assets remained stagnant (Figure 2.2). Growing debt thus took the place of investments in infrastructure and productive capacity in the balancing of aggregate demand with aggregate production capacity. But debt is a tax on the future – it has to be repaid. When interest rates are extremely low, as in the era of the Covid pandemic, growing debt is a relatively minor problem. But these low interest rates depend on a depressed economy. If growth were to revive, the repayment schedules would place a heavy burden on sustainable future growth.

      Whilst Greece’s experience illustrates the power of creditors to contain disruptive defaults, however, it would be wise not to be too sanguine about the dangers to sustained global growth arising from sovereign defaults. The Council on Economic Affairs expressed its concern about the potentially contagious impact of an Italian default.12 Italy’s debt of $3.6tn in 2018 was 131 per cent of GDP, twice the levels permitted by the EU. Italy is the third biggest economy in the EU and an Italian default would hit banks across Europe. If Italy decided to leave the euro currency and return to the lira, this would cause massive losses to investors, triggering another financial crisis.

      And then there is the problem of debt in the emerging economies. Between 2000 and 2017, the value of their dollar debts trebled from less than $1tn to more than $3tn. Their Euro debts more than doubled from around €200tn to more than €550tn. The vulnerability of these emerging-economy debts is not just due to their absolute size and the share of debt in their domestic economies. It is also because much of this debt was transacted in foreign currencies and by the private sector. If a debtor economy willingly or unwillingly devalues its currency, this magnifies the burden on debtors whose earnings are in local currency. A default by a large emerging economy (say Brazil), or perhaps a default by more than one emerging economy (Brazil and Argentina and Indonesia) may have serious repercussions for the sustainability of growth in the global economy. If these debts are contracted to the commercial banking system or to the private corporate sector, these dangers will be magnified.

      Another possible source of disruption which is internal to the financial system is the market in cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoins. These are essentially Ponzi schemes (which are often referred to graphically as pyramid schemes). These schemes generate returns for early investors by bringing in new investors who fund the gains reaped by early entrants. However, the more investors there are in the scheme, the greater the number of new investors required to keep the system growing and to maintain the stability of the pyramid. Thus, Ponzis are inherently unstable. Moreover, because of their need for exponential growth (an ever-growing number of new investors are required to service existing investors), they have a limited life.

      As we will see in Chapter 5, deepening globalization after the mid-1980s helped to rescue falling corporate profitability and prolonged the life of the atrophying Mass Production paradigm. However, outsourcing production to low-wage developing economies had important economic and social consequences. In the economic sphere, it resulted in widespread deindustrialization and persistent imbalances in trade for some of the major high-income economies, notably the US and the UK. In the social sphere, in most of the high-income economies it led to the collapse in employment and income in the rust-belt regions which had powered growth in the Mass Production paradigm’s heyday.

Скачать книгу