The Power In The Land. Fred Harrison

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison страница 18

Автор:
Серия:
Издательство:
The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison

Скачать книгу

landed class did not relent on its demands. The squeeze on profit margins threatened to put many manufacturers out of business, the fate which did in fact await many of them. Radcliffe was aware of the criticisms levelled against landlords, who ‘have been censured for raising their rents at this period, and subsequently still higher’. But he did not begrudge them their exactions. He was, after all, receiving rents from his farms in Mellor.

      Under the ruling system of property rights and taxation laws, of course, Radcliffe was right in predicting how the urban capitalists would have responded had they anticipated the trend in land values. But this does not justify what happened, nor did it relieve Radcliffe of the responsibility for correctly apportioning guilt for the problems which ensued.

      The problems of the cotton industry can be illuminated in theoretical terms. Rent is an economic surplus, the amount left over from production once labour and capital have received their share — a share determined through competition for the opportunity to use the available resources to create new wealth. The amount which is received by capitalists and labourers has to be sufficient to attract them into the most rewarding activities, and enable them to reproduce over time. If landowners are under the pressure of competition, they will be forced to accept the surplus, and no more. In the absence of any inducement to compete, monopoly power enables them to demand a disproportionately large share of output. They are in the happy position of the highwayman who can demand ‘Your money or your life’, but with no risk of retribution. For they control the hangman through the legislature!

      By imposing increasing demands on the wealth-creating agencies, or by refusing to reduce their exactions as the value of output declines, land monopolists eat into the share which ought to go to labour and capital as wages and interest. This is an irrational situation which cannot last for long. The system must break down. Capital is withdrawn when yields become unacceptably low, and investors are deterred from undertaking fresh capital formation. Labour goes hungry and either dies or suffers from malnutrition. Aggregate output contracts, and sooner or later the landlords are forced by realities to accept a cut-back in their rents — or to hold their land idle, in the certain expectation that, sooner or later, the demand for their land will yield the rents they originally demanded.

      For the cotton industry in Radcliffe’s time, unfortunately, there was no fiscal mechanism to force down rents to market levels. The increasing speculation in land forced up rents, squeezed interest and wages, and deterred manufacturers from investing money in power looms. By forcing rents beyond the point of merely appropriating the economic surplus, they were effectively demanding a slice of future output in the current period. This inherently unstable situation must, as it did, lead to a general recession.

      Contemporary historians, who as a group have concentrated on the affairs of the aristocracy and the issues of state, have compounded our problems by their neglecting to study the impact of land monopoly on the first infant industrial system. Prof. Hoskins declared of this period:

      Notes

Скачать книгу