The Power In The Land. Fred Harrison

Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison страница 17

Автор:
Серия:
Издательство:
The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison

Скачать книгу

      First cost of a piece of calico, 28 yards long

      From this we see that the employers were left with a similar profit, and that the difference in the cost of buying twist and weft (the lower cost to foreign buyers being due to their shrewd dealing, according to Radcliffe) was a few pennies. The major difference is in the cost of labour: 4s. Now, if the weaver of Elberfeldt was paying all his living costs, including rent, out of 2s., and given that there was no significant difference in the wages of the Blackburn and Elberfeldt workers, it appears that the English weavers were paying (or having paid for them out of the poor rates) over 4s. in rent! The difference in costs between the two weaving centres is almost wholly attributable to rent. Radcliffe’s data is consistent with the general economic facts of the period.

      The mill owners had to buy or rent more land before they could undertake investment in new technology and reorganise their plants to combine the process of spinning, weaving and finishing the cloth. If rents were at a realistic market level (i.e., the surplus above the returns to labour and capital), this would have been a paying proposition. But rents were penal. A capitalist who undertook the expansion of his factory, and installed the power looms, would have had to have accepted an uncompetitive rate of return on his capital. So it was necessary to retain the use of an obsolete process of production by letting the hand weavers in their damp cellars carry the burden of the rents! Not until 1818 to 1820 did the pressure of speculative rents ease off: and that was when the entrepreneurs undertook their capital investment and modernisation programmes.

      The weavers were obliged to spend long hours in a damp atmosphere in confined workrooms, often cellars near streams; the dampness was necessary to keep the thread supple. The power loom afforded the prospect of dry, healthy working conditions in new factories, as Radcliffe persisted in pointing out. But the machine could not come to their aid: it, too, was a victim of land monopoly.

      The cotton weavers were trapped in a captive labour market. Ideally, they should have been free to decline to work in the industrial sector, which they would have done had their land not been confiscated from them and their forefathers. The entrepreneurs should have had to have attracted them off the land. Wages and working conditions would have had to have been at least as good as what the self-employed farmer/artisan could provide for himself.

      But the freedom to decide one’s future was effectively denied to the workers and those who saved or borrowed to go into business on their own account. Labour and capital were united as victims of the land monopolists, and there was greater sympathy between them than is generally admitted. During the agitations of the time, the weavers who combined to press for higher wages did not propose that these should come out of existing profits: they recommended that prices should be raised. And there were sympathetic employers (Radcliffe was not alone) who did want to raise wages. The landlords in Parliament looked upon these proposals with horror. A general rise in wages would have come out of the ‘surplus’ of the nation’s product, which would have entailed a reduction in rental income.

      The

Скачать книгу